sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Koichi Hamada asks why the business cycle seems to function so differently today than it did when the late Paul Volker was US Fed chief

Koichi Hamada asks why the business cycle seems to function so differently today than it did when the late Paul Volker was US Fed chief

The world has lost a great warrior for price stability. Paul Volcker led a determined campaign to restrain double-digit inflation as the US Federal Reserve’s chair in the 1980s, and exerted a powerful influence over US economic policy for decades to follow. Just a couple of years ago, when he was nearly 90, he grilled me on the inflationary potential of Abenomics, Japanese Prime Minister Shinzo Abe’s economic-reform strategy (I was an adviser on formulating the strategy). But despite Volcker’s praiseworthy achievements, it is worth considering the relevance of his approach in today’s low-inflation environment.

In 1936, when John Maynard Keynes published The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, global price movements were sluggish. Assuming that below-zero inflation would remain relatively rigid, and basing inflation expectations on past outcomes, Keynes prescribed large-scale fiscal expenditure. This helped countries to escape from the deflation of the Great Depression. But after World War II erupted in 1939, inflation surged in many countries, including Greece, Hungary, and the Philippines. In the United States, inflation reached double-digit rates in 1942 and 1947.

When Volcker became Fed chair in August 1979, US inflation was again at double-digit levels – 11.35% – and rising. To rein it in, and stabilize the wider global economy, the Fed hiked interest rates, despite the backlash from some US industries. When he left his post in 1987, the inflation rate was below 4% (its peak since then is 5.4%, in 1990).

During the same period, Robert Lucas – who went on to win the economics Nobel in 1995 – managed to convince a large share of academic economists that they had been formulating expectations wrong: according to his “rational expectations model,” an economic agent’s predictions about the future, not knowledge of history, makes all the difference. According to this approach, monetary policy – especially predictable monetary policy – has little power to change capacity utilization or resource allocation.

With that, the counter-Keynesian macroeconomic revolution appeared to have succeeded. During the Great Moderation, which began in the mid-1980s, business-cycle fluctuations in developed countries became significantly less volatile, and resource allocation was guided by the price mechanism.

But the Great Moderation ended abruptly in 2008, when the subprime mortgage crisis in the US quickly fueled a global financial and economic crisis, which in turn triggered a severe eurozone debt crisis. A Keynesianism resurgence soon followed, with many of the world’s most influential economies embracing stimulus measures, whether fiscal (as in China) or, more commonly, monetary (as in Europe, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the US).

While all of the world’s major advanced-economy central banks rapidly expanded their balance sheets, Japan initially lagged behind the others. After all, its mortgage market was not under the same kind of stress as those in the US and the eurozone. But this imbalance put local industry at a competitive disadvantage, as the yen appreciated against other major currencies. Abenomics, launched in 2013, helped to correct this imbalance, with the Bank of Japan’s accelerating balance-sheet expansion weakening the exchange rate and easing the pressure on Japanese industry.

Since 2008, global inflation and expectations for future prices have broken with the pattern established in the early 1980s. While central banks have continued to pursue 2% inflation, the eurozone and Japan, in particular, have struggled to reach that target. (The US has managed to eke annual inflation of just over 2% since 2017.)

Unlike during Volcker’s era, prices compounded the inflationary inertia, as price formation became a strategic decision amid excess demand. As the CEO of a Japanese-owned international fast-food chain recently told me, he decided not to raise prices after a 2% consumption-tax hike came into effect last October, because he assumed that his competitors would do the same.

Why the mechanism of business cycles has changed so profoundly, or whether it is merely our interpretation of events that has changed, are difficult questions. But there is a concept that can help us answer them: the theory of rational or behavioral inattention.

As the Nobel laureate economist Christopher A. Sims observed in 2003, in the past, it was assumed that economic agents are not only rational, but also computationally unconstrained. But the truth is that people have limited information-processing capacity, so, as the German phenomenologist Edmund Husserl noted, our brains select information to set aside unprocessed. Our behavior – rational or not – is shaped not by all available information, but only by the information to which we pay attention.

During Volcker’s Fed tenure, people were acutely aware of the costs of double-digit inflation, so they would notice and respond – even overreact – to any development that seemed remotely likely to spur inflation. As today’s economic actors set their expectations, they may well be paying attention to very different kinds of developments. Given the powerful role of expectations in determining economic outcomes, this could be enough to alter the functioning of the business cycle.

Economists such as Paul Krugman and Kiminori Matsuyama argue that there are two types of macroeconomic equilibria: one where information is anchored to history, and another where it is anchored to rational expectations about the future. Understanding how economic actors determine which information to process or neglect could go a long way toward revealing the relative importance of history and expectations in determining equilibria, thereby helping policymakers to avoid costly imbalances. Volcker would surely approve of that.


Koichi Hamada, Professor Emeritus of Economics at Yale, is a special adviser to Japan’s prime minister. This content is © Project Syndicate, 2019, and is here with permission.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

4 Comments

Talk to the Millennials if you want to know about expectations, and what is to come. I see a lot of talk putting their behavior down, and very little understanding that their behaviour is quite rational to them. I suspect people don't really want to know the real answer, so don't ask.

Up
0

I was young once. A while ago now, but I too had expectations; of myself, my country, my family, my work life & my relationships, most of which never quite achieved an A. A B perhaps & a C or two, but A's were elusive. Mind you, my expectations (with hindsight) were not that rational, but I didn't know that at the time. Again, with hindsight, we carried a lot of risk for a long time (more than two decades) which once again, I'm not sure we fully comprehended at the time, & it took its toll.
However, back to expectations, living up to other people's expectations was a big focus of ours, and still is today. We're in a business triangle with ourselves at the bottom. Up to the left are our clients. Up to the right are our customers, but more importantly, they are also our client's customers & it's that getting those relationships to work well that creates our business. We facilitate our clients success, not all the time, but we play a key role in generating year round sales for our clients, we like to think a substantial one, but we're biased. Everyone has expectations & you are right to think they are important. It is often relative to those expectations that we judge things, not always, but mostly. Sometimes seeing other people's lives (reality) & expectations is easier that seeing our own. Anyhow, it seemed to work for us.

Up
0

Sounds like Koichi Hamada is a hard core orthodox neo-classical economist. There is no equilibrium! There are no rational expectations because that would be equivalent to knowing the future. Hamada's theory is wrong. All the answers to Hamada's questions can be found by reading a few papers by the likes of Steve Keen.

Up
0

I am baffled. Academically, this guy lives in a different world to me, but I came to the conclusion that we are living in a low inflation world many years ago. In an essay I wrote in mid 2014-Inflation, where to now?- I started with this sentence. "The case I want to make here is that are in an era of structurally low inflation-as opposed to a merely cyclical downturn-an era that I believe will last for a good many years to come".
The best part of 6 years later, the arguments I made then and subsequently remain valid, though I certainly did not foresee an OCR of just 1%. However, it's not quite that straightforward. While our overall inflation rate remains low, there is a wide gap between our non-tradeable and tradeable inflation rates and thus for some whose lifestyle is more tightly bound to the domestic economy, their inflation rate is significantly higher than the nominal figure.
But the 'inflationary elephant in the room' is asset prices. For an explanation, we must turn to Hyman Minsky, an American economist. he wrote in 1974: "The financial system swings between robustness and fragility and these swings are an integral part of the process that generates business cycles". His work was generally ignored until the GFC, when it was rediscovered. Felix martin explains the relevance of this in his book, Money, An Unauthorised Biography. In it, he wrote this; "The more successful a central bank is in mitigating one type of risk by achieving low and stable inflation, the more confident investors will become and the more they will willingly assume other types of risk by investing in uncertain and illiquid securities. Monetary stability will actually breed financial instability".
As a property and stockmarket investor, I have seen this process in action and have benefitted greatly from it. This process unfortunately has the downside effect of exacerbating inequality in our society, as those with few or no such assets, fall ever further behind.

Up
0