By Geof Mortlock*
In December, the Reserve Bank released a consultation paper (Capital Review Paper 4: How much capital is enough?), in which it has proposed a major increase in the capital requirements for banks in New Zealand. The proposed increase in capital ratios for banks puts the Reserve Bank’s proposals well out of line with international norms.
While there is certainly a need to consider the question of what the appropriate minimum capital ratio requirement should be for banks, the Reserve Bank’s consultation paper falls well short of the quality of analysis that is needed to answer this question.
Despite its length (59 pages), the paper contains little substantive argumentation to support the very high capital ratios proposed. It also contains very little cost/benefit analysis. For a central bank that is portrayed by its CEO as a ‘god’ of the ‘financial forest’ (tane mahuta), the quality of analysis is simply not good enough – and certainly falls well short of the mark expected of such a deity.
What has the Reserve Bank proposed?
Before assessing the Reserve Bank’s capital proposals for banks, let’s recap what they have proposed. In brief, the Reserve Bank proposes to:
- set a tier 1 capital requirement (consisting of a minimum requirement of 6% and prudential capital buffer of 9-10%) equal to 16% of risk-weighted assets (RWA) for banks deemed systemically important (the so-called ‘D-SIBs’), and 15% for all other banks; and
- limit the extent to which capital requirements differ between the Internal Ratings Based (IRB) approach and the Standardised approach, by re-calibrating the IRB approach and applying a floor linked to the Standardised outcomes, raising the average RWA for the four IRB-accredited banks to approximately 90% of what would be calculated under the Standardised approach.
The Reserve Bank’s proposal represents a very substantial increase in bank capital requirements relative to current requirements. Currently, banks are required to have a total capital ratio of at least 10.5% of RWA (of which 6% must be in the form of tier 1 capital (essentially issued shares plus retained earnings), 2% in tier 2 capital (such as perpetual or term subordinated debt) and 2.5% as a capital conservation buffer. Under the Reserve Bank’s proposals, the large banks (D-SIBs) will have to meet a prudential capital buffer of 10% of RWA in the form of tier 1 capital, lifting their minimum common equity capital ratio to 14.5% and total tier 1 capital ratio to at least 16% of RWA. Smaller banks will have their tier 1 capital ratios hiked to at least 15%.
How does this compare internationally?
These are extremely high tier 1 capital ratios by international standards. The international norm is for tier 1 capital to be no more than around half of these figures, with some countries then imposing additional capital requirements in the form of additional loss-absorbing capital (often in the form of fixed term or perpetual debt instruments that convert to equity upon a defined non-viability trigger). The Reserve Bank’s proposed capital ratios are considerably higher than those recently proposed by the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA), which would raise the common equity tier 1 ratio for the four major banks in Australia to a minimum of 10.5% of RWA. APRA has proposed no increase in capital for the smaller banks in Australia unless resolution planning reveals a need to do so.
The Reserve Bank’s proposal to limit the gap between average risk weights under the IRB framework (which applies currently to the four major banks) and the average risk weight under the standardised framework (which applies to all other banks) is arbitrary and is also penal by reference to some international norms. It will increase the average RWA calculation of IRB banks to 90% of the outcome under the standardised approach, which is considerably higher than the 72.5% RWA floor finalised by the Basel Committee (the international standard-setter for banking supervision) in December 2017. This will have the effect of further increasing the capital burden on the four IRB accredited banks.
Is the capital increase justified?
The main justification given by the Reserve Bank for increasing the capital ratio requirements for banks is to minimise the damage to the economy and financial system that could result from a bank failure by reducing the probability of bank failure. They have indicated a desire to achieve a probability of bank failure equivalent to around 1 in 200 years.
It is certainly appropriate to be seeking to ensure that banks maintain capital ratios that enable them to survive severe economic and financial shocks, such that bank failures are rare events. That is especially important for the systemically important banks (the D-SIBs), given that their failure could have a major impact on the financial system and economy, and would doubtless involve a substantial amount of resolution funding from the taxpayer if the Australian parent banks were not able or willing to provide the capital funding needed.
However, what is missing in the Reserve Bank’s analysis is any in-depth assessment of the magnitude of shock needed to cause the major banks to fail. The Reserve Bank’s own stress tests indicate that banks come nowhere near to the point of failure under very severe stress scenarios. That being the case, why is a major increase in capital needed?
If they think that the stress tests they have applied are not severe enough, then why do they not recalibrate the tests to even more severe impacts (e.g. through higher and longer contractions in GDP, steeper falls in asset prices and higher and more sustained increases in the rate of unemployment)? Indeed, one would think that, in order to develop capital proposals of the nature contemplated, the Reserve Bank would have undertaken ‘reverse stress tests’. These are used by some foreign supervisory authorities to assess the level of economic and financial shock needed to generate a bank failure. They provide helpful information in assessing how large the economic and financial shock would need to be to cause one or more of the big banks to fail.
It would then be possible to assess the probability of such a magnitude of shock actually occurring. Yet there is no substantive analysis of this in the Reserve Bank’s discussion paper. They appear to have done no reverse stress testing at all. Nor, it seems, has the Reserve Bank asked the banks to undertake reverse stress tests.
All the Reserve Bank do in their paper is draw on international literature that provides high-level (and frankly quite challengeable) data on the level of probability of bank failure associated with given levels of bank capital ratios. That is interesting information. But it tells us little about the magnitude of shock needed in the New Zealand economy to generate bank failures at current levels of capital or the probability of such a severe magnitude of shock occurring.
Moreover, because the data they refer to covers a span of time that includes pre-GFC periods, it does not adequately take into account the strengthening of bank risk management frameworks and governance arrangements that have been part of the post-GFC regulatory environment. These developments would arguably reduce the probability of bank failure for any given capital ratio.
Another deficiency in the Reserve Bank’s analysis is their failure to adequately differentiate between the systemic and economic consequences of a large bank failure from a small bank failure. The failure of a D-SIB (e.g. any of the four largest banks in New Zealand) would have a much greater impact on the economy and financial system (depending on how it is resolved) than would the failure of a small or medium-sized bank.
Yet the Reserve Bank largely ignores this in its capital proposals. It is suggesting that small banks should hold almost as much capital as the D-SIBs, despite the reality that their failure would cause barely a ripple to the financial system (in terms of contagion risk) or economy (in terms of impact on credit channels and adverse wealth effects). In contrast, most other supervisory authorities draw a major distinction between the impacts of D-SIB failure and the impact of small bank failure, and they logically impose considerably lower capital ratio requirements on small banks than on large ones.
A further failing in the Reserve Bank’s analysis is that they take no account at all of the means by which bank failure resolution planning can reduce the economic and financial impact of bank failure and reduce the amount of taxpayer funding that might be needed as part of the resolution process.
Other countries – including Australia and the United Kingdom – have explicitly taken this into account. They have concluded that, with effective bank resolution planning (something the Reserve Bank has largely ignored to date, aside from its ill-conceived Open Bank Resolution policy), small to medium-sized banks that fail can be resolved without the need for high levels of capitalisation. This can be achieved through various techniques, such as ‘purchase and assumption’, merger and bridge bank solutions. That is why most jurisdictions do not impose capital ratios at as high a level on small banks as they do on the systemic banks. Yet the Reserve Bank has completely ignored this reality. It is largely silent on resolution options and the linkage to capital requirement calibration.
The Reserve Bank also ignores the role that deposit insurance plays in a bank failure. Deposit insurance insulates small depositors from loss and provides them with prompt access to their insured deposits. This markedly reduces the adverse impacts of small bank failure. Yet the Reserve Bank paper is silent on the matter. That is probably not surprising given their (largely irrational) opposition to deposit insurance.
However, if a sensibly structured and funded deposit insurance scheme were established in New Zealand – which it should be – then this would significantly reduce the adverse impact of small to medium-sized bank failures. All else equal, it would provide an argument for lower capital ratios for small banks than for larger banks, subject of course to bank levies being calibrated on the basis of their risk profile.
Another failure in the Reserve Bank’s analysis is the importance of bank risk appetite settings, risk management and governance arrangements in influencing the probability of failure. They ignore it completely. Instead, the Reserve Bank places 100% emphasis on the role of capital in minimising the probability of bank failure. In reality, many factors come into play in influencing a bank’s probability of failure, including capital, liquidity, credit exposure concentration, funding concentration, quality of lending, risk appetite, quality of risk management systems and controls, and governance arrangements.
That is why a professional supervisory authority, such as APRA or Canada’s OSFI, put such emphasis on comprehensive requirements for governance and risk management frameworks, risk appetite settings and the like. It is also why these supervisory authorities invest the time, resource and expertise in on-site bank assessments, benchmarking analysis between banks, and comprehensive preventive and corrective action frameworks.
In contrast, the Reserve Bank still keeps its head in the sand on these matters. It is content to be a ‘light touch’ ‘reluctant regulator’ on all of these matters that so heavily influence the probability of bank failure. And yet they now seem to be the ‘rogue and reckless regulator’ when it comes to seeking to put all of the financial system soundness eggs in the capital basket and to increase tier 1 capital ratios to levels unseen in most countries. Where is the balance in this? It seems that the Reserve Bank is happy to impose a very large tax on banks (and bank customers) in order to continue to enable it to continue to be the reluctant regulator and supervisor it is in respect of the details of bank risk assessment.
A further piece of the jigsaw puzzle missing in the Reserve Bank’s paper is the absence of any discussion of bank recovery planning. Internationally, most OECD supervisory authorities have, since around 2010/11, required banks to develop, maintain and regularly test recovery plans. These are comprehensive plans that set out the means by which banks would restore themselves to financial soundness in the face of a capital or liquidity shock. They are an essential element in the risk management framework of any bank. All else equal, the more comprehensive and reliable is a bank’s recovery capacity, the lower is the risk of bank failure.
Yet, unlike other supervisors, the Reserve Bank has done nothing to require banks to establish, maintain and test comprehensive recovery plans and to link them to their risk management frameworks. All their focus has been on ‘separation plans’ to enable a New Zealand subsidiary of an Australian parent bank to be separated from the parent bank in a failure situation, which merely reflects the continuing irrational paranoia the Reserve Bank has about the Australian authorities in a bank failure scenario.
If comprehensive recovery planning requirements were introduced for all banks in New Zealand, that would achieve at least two things. It would shed light on each bank’s capability of restoring themselves to financial soundness from an impaired capital position (and hence the amount of capital needed). And it would strengthen their recovery capability and thereby lower the probability of failure (without necessarily increasing capital ratios).
The Reserve Bank’s paper is also very light in its justification for requiring IRB banks to have an average risk weight of not less than 90% of the average risk weight under the Standardised model. This is a significant proposal and one that could impose significant capital costs on the D-SIBs with flow-on effects to borrowers and depositors alike. It is perfectly reasonably for the Reserve Bank to rigorously assess the analysis underpinning banks’ IRB calculations of risk. The Bank should be doing this as part of its supervisory approach. However, imposing an arbitrary floor on IRB risk weights is a costly and inefficient approach to achieving the goal of ensuring that IRB outcomes reflect risk accurately. Much more analysis is needed by the Reserve Bank on this matter, especially if they are proposing a risk weight floor that is more conservative (penal in impact) than in other comparable countries.
Finally, the Reserve Bank’s paper is incredibly light on cost/benefit analysis. It notes in a sentence or two that higher capital ratios might lead to higher interest rates and reduced credit availability, but dismisses this as insignificant. Yet there is no quantification of these impacts. They should undertake a substantive cost/benefit assessment of the effect of higher capital ratios on lending rates and deposit rates, on bank risk appetite and on the likely effect on credit availability. This is essential if we are to meaningfully assess the impact of the proposals on the economy and bank customers.
Likewise, there is no mention of the impact of the capital proposals on the contestability of the banking system – i.e. whether introducing one of the highest capital ratio requirements in the world would make it less attractive for new entrants (domestic or foreign) to enter the banking system, with reduced competitiveness and efficiency for the financial system and economy. And there is next to no analysis of the impact on competitive neutrality in the proposals – i.e. whether this would impose competitive burdens on small banks relative to large banks (given that the failure of a small bank is systemically insignificant) or the competitive non-neutrality vis a vis non-bank deposit-takers. Given that efficiency of the financial system is one of the implied objectives of the Reserve Bank, one could reasonably expect much more comprehensive analysis of the financial system efficiency issues that arise from the proposals.
All in all, the Reserve Bank’s proposals are poorly thought through and unsupported by analysis. The Reserve Bank needs to fundamentally reassess what is being proposed and provide much stronger argumentation and facts to support it, backed by a comprehensive cost/benefit assessment. Treasury needs to step up here too. They need to independently review what the Reserve Bank is proposing, either themselves or by commissioning a report from an independent expert.
New Zealanders can reasonably expect a lot more from its banking regulator, in terms of quality of analysis, than it is getting.
(You can see interest.co.nz's three part series on the Reserve Bank capital proposals here, here and here).
*Geof Mortlock, of Mortlock Consultants Limited, is an international financial consultant who undertakes extensive assignments for the International Monetary Fund, World Bank and other organisations globally, dealing with a wide range of financial sector policy issues. He formerly worked at senior levels in the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority and Reserve Bank of New Zealand.
27 Comments
“The Reserve Bank’s proposed capital ratios are considerably higher than those recently proposed by the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority “
So what? Aside for the rather dubious reputation that APRA(**) has as a dispenser of wet lettuce leaves, you note:
“…failure could have a major impact on the financial system and economy, and would doubtless involve a substantial amount of resolution funding from the taxpayer if the Australian parent banks were not able or willing to provide the capital funding needed. “
So the Australian comparator is not appropriate. New Zealand is small, so it needs to take an ‘overcautious’ approach to its financial system- we could be on our own if it gets nasty.
(**Geof Mortlock.... formerly worked at senior levels in the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority)
APRA... The 'A'ustralian 'P'iss a'R'tists 'A'ssociation.
They have had no idea about what has been going on in the banking and financial sector and we are about to hear today that they were drunk at the wheel!
Higher capital ratios are essential for NZ because of our extreme exposure to one asset class. around 70% of all lending, despite what the bank lobbyists suggest.
While I agree that more analysis is always needed, especially in the follow on effects of implementing a higher ratio. I do disagree above that the higher stress tests were not done. No doubt they were done, but not published. Would not be hard to plug different variables into a Excel sheet and present the boss with 5 scenarios which they only publish one to the public. Better to plan for the worst and hope for the best.
As a retired professional engineer with only a smattering of banking knowledge and having followed a number of banking articles and the comments in interest.co.nz, I believe banking regulation requires a stick and carrot approach. The bigger the stick the better with a small carrot, especially with regard to capital ratios. I think there's enough horsepower at RBNZ. not to even enter consultation/discussion with the banks on capital raios but should specify what's required. The ratios they have proposed would be higher than with what will be ended up, purely as a negotiating tactic.
Regarding a cost/benefit analysis on capital ratios. Probably an exercise in futility and bound to end up in analysis paralysis. A nice, cost/benefit analysis report by expensive consultants no doubt.
It also astounds me that this is the first governor in 10? years to attempt to level the playing field between NZ owned banks and the overseas ones, specifically the Ozzie owned banks, with regard to capital ratios.
The use of "Internal Models" should definitely be changed. All they do is provide a competitive advantage to the big four banks in terms of reduced funding costs, while transferring the additional risk to NZ deposit holders/Tax payers.
The Big four banks use these lower funding costs to just squeeze more profit out of the country, rather than actually pass on any benefit to NZ consumers. Make it a level playing field.
I'd be interested to know who Geof is actually consulting for right now? Having never contributed to the site until this issue arose, but all of sudden we have a flood of articles that co-incidentally just happen to align with the interests of the Big Four banks? Really?
Miguel, I can't comment on who Geof's clients may be. But he has previously written a few articles on other topics for interest.co.nz. They are here - https://www.interest.co.nz/category/people/geof-mortlock
Fair enough. When I click on his name on the article a get "user for 1 month, 3 days" with only three associated articles (all about the same topic). It seems to be based on how earlier articles were published (previous articles were published by other users).
Thanks for the extra info. Gives a better scope of the contributions made.
'Systemic crises happen when bank credit creation for non-GDP (i.e. asset purchase) transactions expands for several years significantly above growth rate of the long run ability to service bank debt, aka national income or GDP. Quantity Theory of Credit'
https://eprints.soton.ac.uk/36569/
"The Reserve Bank’s own stress tests indicate that banks come nowhere near to the point of failure under very severe stress scenarios. That being the case, why is a major increase in capital needed? "
Clearly the RBA is concerned, whether it says so publicly or not, about the real possibility of a bigger shock to the system. With the Sydney and Melbourne housing market declining very rapidly right now, with many forecasts of greater than 25-30% declines, and with a similar bubble in NZ, that's got to be a major factor here. They also have the very real precedents from the GFC, such as the housing busts in Ireland and Spain, and of course the US situation.
The real question is, will it be too late if there is a housing bust, given this is happening over the next 5 years?
The capital adequacy ratio is really a made up figure out of necessity. A bank is by definition a deposit-taker i.e. it is expected to match its lending to its customers primarily with deposits. What topples a bank is a combination of reckless lending (no diversification by industry sector, debt backed by collateral that become worthless in unfavorable economic events etc ), loss of faith on part of its creditors ( creditors crushing to withdraw their monies) and a serious downturn of economy (mass job losses, hyper inflation etc).
in such event, 15% is really no different to 10%. in any other scenario, a bank failure is likely to be isolated (i.e. not the whole banking sector will be affected), the amount of their loss likely to be limited (i.e. 10% is likely to be enough).
So 15% is not good enough to stop the banking industry melting, and it is too much for preventing isolated and smaller scale events.
Prudent lending is where you can control bank failure in NZ. Not capital adequacy. But that is much harder to do. I believe that this 15% thing is so RBNZ looks to be doing something, without actually doing what they really need to do.
2007-08 provide banks collapse due to liquidity and freezing up of inter-bank trust conditions.
All the major US and most of leading UK banks came under extreme pressure and several major US banks failed or had to merge under duress. The stress tests are a joke. The big 4 in NZ are Australian and 65% of their "asset" base is in fact DEBT that they lend on mortgages. So, when (not IF) those mortgages get into negative equity or simply lose 20% of their value with all huge knock n effects on Australian consumption, there will be hell to pay. That ignores the elephant which is China debt and the markets pathetic complacency re that going tits up, which it will. Money should be province of democratic control, ie government. Of course this is too "dangerous" and government cannot be trusted not to go mad printing money. Er? Sound familiar? QE etc. Democracy is only allowed when not important - ie at work and in finance. Just happens to be the two areas ruling class keep to themselves, in terms of wealth and autonomy. Also, can readersplemse remember that deposits are not basis of lending! Banks create money from loans, they do not wait for deposits. This is critical and seems STILL not to be understood by more than 5% of population
The answer has to be to cut the dividend payout ratio's of the large banks which are as high as the early 80's, simply inappropriate for highly levered, systemically important institutions. Bring it down to 50% and let them build up capital via retained earnings. Many Australian investors are addicted to the sugar hit of the high franked dividends but this is all part of the adjustment necessary (and likely to come later today) for a more ethical and safer banking sector.
Corporate finance theory would say share price should be unchanged (they are making the same profit, just paying less of it out as a dividend), but likely they would fall a some investors need the cash-flow. The share price really doesn't impact the capital position on a day to day basis.
Corporate finance theory would say share price should be unchanged (they are making the same profit, just paying less of it out as a dividend), but likely they would fall a some investors need the cash-flow. The share price really doesn't impact the capital position on a day to day basis.
Te Kooki - Yes that would be your answer and every customer who isn't a shareholder but that's unlikely to be the complete way it plays out. They are public companies with a share price to protect and it would be considerably naive to think that the shareholder will pay more than a modest portion of the cost. It's a bank regulator requirement and a cost that will be passed onto the customer with the minor consolation that if youre a depositor at least your credit risk will be reduced since you'll be dealing with the most capitalised/over capitalise banking system in the world
Perhaps part of the RB decision is based on NZ not having a deposit insurance scheme (which may be a political decision) and that as we are a small country controlled by an overseas Banking cartel then the country has to be protected by requiring that cartel to hold greater Tier 1 capital. Sounds good to me. That the cartel might therefore be restricted in what it can pay out to its shareholders, is in my view, irrelevant. New Zealand comes first.
Who is the insurer in such a scheme btw?
If its the Government then in effect its the tax payer and its a regressive atx, ie the poorest will pay the bill to insure those with {a lot more} than them. Personally I see that as wrong and frankly I dont want to guarantee others money nor should I have to. If on the other hand its purely a private matter with a [re-]insurance company I am all for it if the "saved" wants to pay.
But the sane line of thinking would be that the insurance premium is charged to those that are covered.. in propetion to the amount of cover they need. So effectively it would be a reduction in interest paid as the deposit guarantee skims its fee from the depositor.
No, Steven it Is NOT the taxpayer. I suggest you listen to Prof Bill Mitchell to find out how it is done.https://youtu.be/IynNfA1Ohao. He has any many lectures to listen to.
Prof Richard Werner
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=EC0G7pY4wRE&t=51s
I think regardless of whether you agree with Geof or not it is important that the NZ public are able to challenge the RBNZ on its rationale and methodology.
My concern here is the RBNZ are primarily focussed on making sure the NZ banks don't fail by imposing a higher capital requirement.... I don't begrudge them that at all... but how much caution is too much? Why not make them hold 50% of assets as capital?
I note the RBNZ in their consultation believed that there would be only a minor impact on mortgage and deposit rates and banks would achieve the capital required by retained earnings.... yet every piece of research thus far (and sheer common sense) suggests otherwise.
Banks shareholders expect management to allocate the capital to ensure the highest return on capital. By insisting the banks allocate more capital to Risk Weighted Assets in NZ we need to ask ourselves what is the logical response.... either banks require a higher return or they will (slowly) allocate capital where it does produce a higher return.
I am pleased Geof as an independent person is raising the above questions about the RBNZ methodology as it is extremely difficult for the banks.
Like a bank failure, an overly cautious RBNZ could have significant implications on all NZers and there needs to be a question asked if the RBNZ have perhaps gone too far.
There is a simple,but radical solution to the problem the Reserve Bank is trying to solve. It was put forward during the depths of the Great Depression by the renowned American economist Irving Fisher.
In his paper,100% Money,he wrote this:"The checking deposit department of the bank would become a mere storage warehouse for for bearer money belonging to its depositors and would be given a separate corporate existence as a Check Bank". Such a bank would do no other business and would be backed by sovereign money.These banks would not be allowed to do any other business.
Every other activity which banks might wish to undertake would have no sovereign backing and would be subject to only light supervision. This proposal became known as the Chicago Plan,but got no traction. It was revived by Milton Friedman in the 70s and a few years ago,was again studied by the IMF who found,using a mathematical formula,that it would lead to greater macroeconomic and financial stability.
Sadly,I can't see it happening,nor can I see the monopoly enjoyed by the big 4 banks being seriously questioned. It would be in the country's best interests if they were broken up,but it isn't going to happen
We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.
Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.