This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.
One of the reasons I wrote Not in Narrow Seas: An Economic History of Aotearoa New Zealand was my irritation at how often conventional histories of the country ignore the impact of the economy on what happened. I chose to provide an account in which the economy (and technology) played a fuller role, rather than illustrate the various failures; I did not want it to be a grumbling book. Allow me one illustration.
I greatly admire Keith Sinclair’s scholarship. I valued, among his other historical works, A Destiny Apart: New Zealand's Search for a National Identity which tells of how towards the end of the nineteenth century New Zealand seriously contemplated joining the federation of Australian states, completed in 1901. As the merger became more formulated we chose an independent destiny. Sinclair does not mention that the New Zealand economy was more depressed in the 1880s than that of the Australian states, but that prosperity returned here faster in the 1890s (as the pastoral boom took off).
Surely, with the economic prosperity New Zealanders became more confident of being able to go it alone. I am not saying that was decisive, but it must have been relevant. It is noticeable that when we are doing badly economically relative to Australia, cries for joining them tend to be stronger.
The lack of economic history recurs in the proposals for the new history school curriculum, as you might expect if the designers were ignorant of economic history. Anyone would think the economy is irrelevant; perhaps the devisers of the curriculum are not aware that it is the economy which pays their salaries.
It is a contemporary problem too. Far too much public policy ignores economics. Consider the Three Waters proposal which transfers responsibility for drinking water, wastewater and stormwater to four entities, consolidating the current local government provision. The original proposal said that it had not worked out the financial implications of the redisorganisation. Even so decisions were made.
The background economics is that our local authorities, dependent on rates for their income, are underfunded. To cover the deficit, they have practised one of the oldest tricks in the accounting book – not providing sufficiently for the running down of their capital. Best do it for infrastructure which is not visible. Water is generally underground; out of sight, out of mind until it fails.
The Auditor-General recently reported that the amount local councils spent renewing pipes and other plant was 74 per cent of depreciation for water supply, 64 per cent for wastewater and just 39 per cent for stormwater; these were higher rates than for earlier years. (Christchurch is excluded because it had to spend up large post-quake.)
The redisorganisation will make the three waters infrastructure more visible with the expectation that the waters will be better looked after. That will be costly. The minister introducing the policy stupidly said the new configuration will lower local body rates since they wont have to fund local water supplies from them. What she did not say was how the new entities will be funded. By rates? By user charges? By central government subsidies out of its tax revenue? The lack of answers is an omission comparable to leaving the economy out of our history.
It is not simply a matter of higher charges somewhere in the system. Who pays will matter. Consider the clumsy entity which runs from East Cape to Nelson. Will the East Capers be paying for Nelson’s water infrastructure or the other way around? Perhaps the expectation is that Wellingtonians will pay for both. Who knows? Certainly not those designing the system.
There are many other examples of proposed redisorganisations which ignore the economics. The general impression is that government advisers are often as incapable of thinking about economics as historians are. I conclude with another example, the proposed RNZ-TVNZ merger.
The driver for the redisorganisation is the convergence of delivery platforms as indicated by RNZ’s renaming from ‘Radio New Zealand’. Today it delivers by radio, by television and by broadband. TVNZ is facing a similar convergence, especially with its advertising funding being undermined by new competitors. There is a logic to merging the two if the economics is ignored.
RNZ and TVNZ are funded differently. RNZ is dependent upon public funding; TVNZ upon commercial advertising. We are told that the funding division will be maintained – that there will be no additional public funding – but that it will not impact on how the entities work. (Those who tell us will not be around when their promises turn to custard. Perhaps we should tag politicians’ public pensions with the requirement that they be cut when their promises fail; it would result in fewer manifestly undeliverable promises.)
The catch is that the two funding modes are not in harmony. There will be pressures to raid the public funding to bolster the commercial funding, undermining the independence and public good elements of RNZ. We have already seen that happening within TVNZ, as the ineffective changes to it under the Clark-Cullen Government illustrate. When you are competing against others, you raid the easy money to strengthen your competition, just as when you are broke you run down infrastructure.
We will be told that provisions will be made to prevent TVNZ’s commercial arm raiding RNZ’s public service one. Yeah right. Accountants are smarter than politicians, as the Department of Internal Affair’s accounting practices have shown when they raid the funding for their archives and library activities for other purposes.
The easy solution is to fiddle the way overheads are charged. It will be simple to overcharge RNZ for its share, transferring the public funds to commercial TVNZ, thereby compromising public service broadcasting. Or newsrooms could be merged, biasing news gathering toward the audience most responsive to advertising.
It has happened before. Read Ian Cross’s memoirs The Unlikely Bureaucrat and Such Absolute Beginners. As chairman of the BCNZ he was bedevilled by the pressures between radio and television, between public funding and advertising.
Too much policy is ignorant of economics. Nor does it learn from history. As they say in the financial industry just before the next crash, ‘this time it is different’.
Brian Easton, an independent scholar, is an economist, social statistician, public policy analyst and historian. He was the Listener economic columnist from 1978 to 2014. This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.
11 Comments
The lack of economic history recurs in the proposals for the new history school curriculum, as you might expect if the designers were ignorant of economic history.
What a strange comment. Graeme Ball was my history teacher and in every case study the economic side was covered in good detail, it provided great context for the events that unfolded. I can't say we covered any history in my economics classes.
The problem is that the comment is wrong. In fact, it all is.
"in which the economy (and technology)
No - it's an input of energy, which did some work, applied to something. Fuel, diggers, pipes, in 3 waters case. The problem is that society has no been earmarking the energy and materials ahead, for................. anything. For pension-underwriting, for instance. We just have a collection of blind forward bets.
Increasingly, there has been less and less real underwrite, so entropy has been insufficiently parried (things have been allowed to decay).
You don't - can't - fix that economically, nor can you do it by centralising control. You can ONLY do it by indulging in more entropy-parrying. Which will take ever-more energy and materials. Which, in a depleting world (call it supply chain issues if you need to dodge reality) will be increasingly contested. Triage has already started - by the LCs. It won't stop because the operations are called-in, and it won't stop because everyone suddenly becomes economics-savvy - indeed, believing economists has been most of the problem.
Three Waters is interesting to me, why are Government willing to go all-in on this but not more popular policies like KiwiBuild or the Auckland Light Rail? If you where going to put a stake in the ground it'd be on a really meaningful, transformative policy. Essentially all of this could be cleared up by legislating councils fully fund drinking, waste and stormwater by creating reserves to cover future liabilities but instead we've engineered a mountain out of a molehill.
The problem with the status quo is small councils don't have the scale or expertise to manage three waters. If all the rules and regulations are coming from central government why on earth doesn't central government also fund and deliver it? The only plausible reason is political, i.e. they don't want to take the risk/responsibility for delivery.
https://www.rnz.co.nz/news/national/433047/new-plymouth-faces-decade-of…
"After the initial 12 percent hit, rates are proposed to go up on average 7 percent in each of the next nine years."
I'm dreading the inflation adjustment that will no doubt be added on top of this once they've redone their sums.
When I consider our economists I am reminded of David Lange's reef fish analogy. They have never delivered good guidance of upcoming issues. They are full of backward looking comments relating to what has already happened. They forget the ecc101 basics of their subject in favor of what ever is the populist theme of the moment. Why take any notice of them at all.
"The background economics is that our local authorities, dependent on rates for their income, are underfunded."
It is equally arguable that for decades councils have been overfunded and wasted many millions of ratepayers money on their personal vanity projects while wilfully ignoring basic civic infrastructure to enable gross expansion of their mission scope creep.
Councils (at least in Auckland) used to raid money collected for waters and use it elsewhere. This was thankfully undone when Watercare was separated out from politicians and bureaucrats and run by technicians with their own revenue collection mechanism.
I could see the merit in expanding Watercare under its same operating model. The danger is we'll have accountants, bureaucrats and politicians gaining too much influence in Three Waters once more and encumbering the technicians who should be managing and executing the work.
Hmm! Where to start? Well, there is certainly a grain of truth here, but that's it. Many of issues highlighted are accounting issues and not economics.
However, when we broaden the picture we can begin to see the damage that economists can wreak. I am sure Mr Easton will be familiar with the Mont Pelerin Society, members of which led the headlong move to neo-liberalism and have done much damage. A very short version of this play( a true tragedy) can be found in pages 68/70 of Doughnut Economics.
I would go further. Economists wanted their discipline to be not a social science-which it really is- but a hard science, to be compared with say pyhsics. To do so required mathematical formulae to be adopted. A good primer on this can be found in Econned by Yves Smith. Chapter 4 is headed; Neoclassical Economics: The triumph of simplistic math over messy facts. If you want a laugh, have a look at the Arrow-Debreu theorem.
In other words, most economists should be tightly corralled. If let loose on an economy, they can wreak havoc. However, to be fair, I think the discipline is improving and the growth of Behavioural Economics is evidence of that.
We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.
Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.