sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Brian Easton says property rights are critical to an economy

Public Policy / opinion
Brian Easton says property rights are critical to an economy
propertyrf1
Source: 123rf.com

This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.


Property rights – which enable decisions over tangible and intangible assets – are critical to an economy as Why Nations Fail pointed out.

Not just private property rights for, as we shall see, they are more complicated than that. Neoliberals argue that private property rights lead to the maximum economic prosperity; they used that to justify privatisation. Certainly, ambiguous property rights are likely to result in poor quality outcomes. But community property rights can be effective, as economic orthodoxy acknowledged when Elinor Ostrom was awarded a Nobel laureateship in 2009 for showing that the use of exhaustible resources by groups of people can be rational and prevent their depletion without either state intervention or markets with private property.

Pre-market Māori demonstrated that too. The seas around Northland were teaming with fish, even in the 1850s. The local hapu had various measures which sustained them. Following the breakdown in hapu authority, the seas became fished out.

The neoliberal misunderstanding was evident in the original formulation of ACT’s treaty principles proposal. Its second principle stated that the government should ‘protect all New Zealanders’ authority over their land and other property’. This was intended to be an updating of Article II of Te Tiriti, which actually stated that the Māori rangatiratanga would be preserved for ‘ratou wenua o ratou kainga me o ratou taonga katoa’, which might be translated as ‘their lands, their villages and all their treasured things’.

Two things. Minor for the purposes here, ‘ratou taonga katoa’ (all their treasured things) is wider than just property. Did ACT intend to downgrade the standing of te reo, despite the highest courts in the land determining that it is a taonga under Article II?

But second, the notion of rangatiratanga is not just about individual authority. Pre-market Māori did not have a notion of individual ownership of land and other resources. Those property rights were exercised communally.

This was barely understood by the first Europeans and led to many early misunderstandings, some of which persist to this day, for we are always tempted to anachronistically interpret the past by current standards. (The misunderstandings are well explored in the scholarly literature; I tried to summarise them in Chapters 4 and 5 of Not in Narrow Seas.)

(Those of a conspiratorial frame of mind may think that ACT was not ignorant but was trying to sneak into legislation a clause which the courts could interpret as upholding the principles in ACT’s Regulatory Standards Bill.)

Clearly, ACT’s second principle will not do, and sober official advice changed its manifesto promise to

          Rights of hapu and iwi Māori — the Crown recognises the rights that hapu and iwi had when they signed the Treaty/te Tiriti. The Crown will respect and protect those rights. Those rights differ from the rights everyone has a reasonable expectation to enjoy only when they are specified in Treaty settlements.

(ACT has lost interest in this revised second principle but is proceeding with the Regulatory Standards Bill.)

This still does not capture the essence of Article II of Te Tiriti. I’d have thought that the rights existed from the time of signing and that treaty settlements only recognised the existing rights rather than created them.

There is also a deep complication about what property rights refers to. It is not peculiar to Te Tiriti, so I begin with a contemporary example.

Suppose there was a proposal to establish a KFC in a suburban shopping centre. Even a neoliberal living, say, 100m away might object to its impact on the neighbourhood and join in the objection to its establishment. (In the case in mind, they were successful and the KFC was never established.) There is nothing among a property owner’s legal rights which entitles them to block the proposal. The opportunity to object arose from town-planning provisions such as in the Resource Management Act. But presumably the neoliberal thought there was some existing moral right to block a neighbour’s peaceable, if detrimental, activities.

(You can see why proposed changes to the RMA and the proposed fast track legislation are difficult. While they are intended to reduce the transaction costs of making decisions, they will also reduce some people’s ‘property rights’ while increasing those of others.)

We frequently see Māori claiming kaitiakitanga (guardianship) in their rohe, despite its ownership having been legally alienated. They are arguing that the rangatiratanga of Article II of Te Tiriti included stewardship rights and mana whenua was not alienated when ownership was transferred (whether justly or unjustly). They are not alone in their belief of kaitiakitanga rights. Greenies frequently invoke it; we are all greenies on occasions (as with the raising of the level of Lake Manapouri, even if we had never visited it and lived miles away).

ACT does not seem to have thought through these issues in its proposals, or perhaps neoliberals do not think they should be attended to (unless it’s about a KFC in their neighbourhood). But others do.

ACT has opened up a can of worms. The biggest worm in the property rights can is to what extent their existing distribution is just. (This is not quite the same issue as the inequality of the property rights.)

The respected libertarian philosopher Robert Nozick pointed out that if a distribution is ‘just’, the distribution of rights remains just following voluntary transactions. But what if the original position is not just, what if transactions are not voluntary? How can we treat the existing distribution as acceptable?

Was the distribution of land just even on 6 February 1840? As a reult of the Musket Wars much land involuntarily changed its rangatiratanga. Oral traditions report that there were involuntary land transfers following conquest even earlier. Was there ever a time when the distribution of land was just? Arguably the proto-Māori seized the land from the existing animal inhabitants, when they first arrived.

A practical resolution might be to say that the distribution on 6 February 1840 was acceptable in the governance of New Zealand. Even so, much of the subsequent alienation was not voluntary.

The tendency is to highlight the consequences of the New Zealand Wars – we do love heroics. Arguably, the 1865 Native Lands Act was far more destructive. It created the Māori Land Court, which converted Māori customary title into a title recognisable under law. Māori were not consulted about this legislation. British law was unable to deal effectively with collective (customary Māori ) ownership, so Māori practices were converted to individualised ownership. The creation of a commercial title with its individualisation pitted Māori against Māori, undermining the integrity of hapu. (Woody Guthrie sang ‘some rob you with a six-gun/some with a fountain pen.’) Here is a salutary reminder that property rights influence the way we organise society.

Nozick is ruled out. So how are we settle on an acceptable distribution of property rights? ACT’s Treaty Principles Bill is not an answer.


*Brian Easton, an independent scholar, is an economist, social statistician, public policy analyst and historian. He was the Listener economic columnist from 1978 to 2014. This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

16 Comments

Those rights differ from the rights everyone has a reasonable expectation to enjoy only when they are specified in Treaty settlement

Article 2 guarantees as being for “nga Rangatira ki nga hapu-ki nga tangata katoa o Nu Tirani,” or “the chiefs, the subtribes and all the people of New Zealand”

ALL

Equal rights for all seems more likely what the global super power of the time agreed to.

 

Up
4

You're missing the context that "all the people of New Zealand" was defined by the British at the time (even in the Oxford dictionary) as Maori people. The British immigrants saw themselves as British, not New Zealander. To be part of the Empire was a far more honourable thing than to be associated with primitive NZ. They were also vastly outnumbered by Maori people locally. And of course many of the British elite involved in these negotiations never intended to stay in NZ, they were essentially diplomats on a mission of conquest.

Even into the middle of the 20th century people would often prefer to be seen as part of the Empire than a kiwi.

Up
3

You're missing the context

Such is the problem of todays arguments about the treaty. It means whatever you want it to mean. 

Up
6

Wouldn't go that far. It's a contract, and there's norms around how you interpret a contract, even an old one. Our Common Law system is basically designed to do this iterative reinterpretation of things in a particular direction to suit the common times, while also acknowledging the norms and context of the times the agreement was signed. And the legal fraternity can be creative where they want to be. Many older agreements are fairly abhorrent and outright prejudiced, especially those from around the time of our treaty, so sometimes courts like to soften that up a bit or gloss over the bits that nobody would find acceptable in modern times.

Our treaty was signed between two pretty ruthless hereditary monarchistic and undemocratic peoples. On that basis I can't see how you arrive at a conclusion the treaty meant to infer equality for all people and reflect a democratic society with equal rights and responsibilities. But creative interpretations abound.

Up
1

Wouldn't go that far. It's a contract, and there's norms around how you interpret a contract, even an old one

It's a contract, which is a loaded arrangement if one party has a different interpretation of what the contractual relationship is or means. And I will suggest that the idea of a contract is completely different between British colonial admin and the participating chiefs in Tiriti. 

  Even in a contemporary context, the idea of contractual relationships is different between Asia and the West. In the East (and Russia), the legal construct is often secondary. Not always. But often. 

Up
1

Interestingly you cannot have an illegal contract....and who makes the law in a parliamentary democracy?

Up
0

The Maori party argument reminds me of the classic book, Animal farm.

Every one is equal, the pigs are just more equal.

Up
6

Every one is equal, the pigs are just more equal.

Which is my concern too. But within Maori society. Quite often white liberal society likes to paint a 'noble savage' picture of what a sovereign Maori nation looks like (which to me is inherently racist in itself). Let's remember stratification in traditional Maori society:

  • Rangatira: Leaders or chiefs who are descendants of significant ancestors. Their authority is often based on both age and seniority.
  • Commoners (tauwareware): Generally the junior kin of rangatira, they participated actively in community life but had less formal power.
  • Slaves (taurekareka): Often captives from war, they had limited rights but were sometimes integrated into whānau through intermarriage.

What concerns me is that it appears that those calling the shots in Maori politics are often more privileged than say impoverished Maori.

Is there any guarantee those people's interests at the bottom of the pile are going to be elevated? 

Up
4

Yep. 

And what everyone is missing is the different perspective and perception to the natural world.

One really needs to study and be willing to understand the philosophy and meaning behind kaitiaikitanga, taonga etc. It's the same with Aborigines, First Nations, people's, Pagans etc. They had an expanded view of our relationship with the Earth and Nature. It's why there are terms for Mother Earth. They did not believe in ownership of the land, one cannot own their mother. It was a foreign concept. This, I believe is what they expected to be able to continue to honour. They were willing to share and teach their knowledge. 

But the colonists came in with a dominance mindset. One of rule and ownership over everything. One of possession, and the view that everything, including fellow humans are an expendable resource to be used for one's own gain. It's the ultimate form of violence.

This I believe this is the heart of the matter both here and overseas. It's the root cause of inequality. This mindset is built into our economics and capitalism.

Up
1

It is simply a question of scale.

Consider the demands of any society that grows above its ability to supply itself...what are their options? They can seek further resources from without....or they can seek to go where there are resources unused. If you see resources nearby that are 'owned' by another you may seek to access them by various means or you may chance your arm (or be required to) and seek resources elsewhere. NZ pre europeans had an estimated population of less than 200,000 and yet there was still conflict....ask yourself why various Maori Waka made a journey into the unknown 800-1000 years ago....and then along come europeans seeking more resources and the problem accentuates.

People are people.

Up
1

The MLC has much to answer for individualised titles and the problems kept coming in my opinion ...because thru the generations these titles are no longer individualised . The changes in the Native lands act thru to TTWMA 93 have resulted in shareholds that have split (down usually) and as a result some holders have holdings that are worth less than the cost of recording them. Those that have managed to maintain holdings of any value will struggle to break their share out and face fierce resistance from other holders in many cases. It is estimated over 90% of Maori land was disposed of via individual ownership and the heat is on the last few holders to NOT sell or individualise these holdings.

No European would tolerate such a land tenure system and whilst Tribal Authority must be recognised  should it reach as far as capturing what was once an individualised freehold title. If tribes have a problem then surely they should have sought compensation via their treaty claims. Others caught in the sharehold Maori land trap should have sought compensation for having to endure a land tenure system that has evolved into what may be perceived as forced collectivism in this day and age. Should tribes or indeed the MLC have any influence over a system that was originally designed to grant individual ownership .  The fear is that Maori whom are able to break the chains of the MLC  will sell off the last remaining land to capitalise on what for many has been a zero return holding. Projects that permit building on land but not on foundations that penetrate into the ground have gone some way to housing some but at the end of the day these folk are subject to a court that leans away from an act that was originally devised to empower individualism. The value of a communual land holding is nominal compared to full freehold. It could be argued that the original sole owners were Chiefs in their own right able to exercise full authority over their holding...the same cannot be said today .... Maori that hold shares are infinitely better off buying freehold than attempting to engage with the MLC and all its whims.    MY opinion.... (critical)  

  

Up
0

A poll on NZissues found that at least 92% of people will leave NZ if the new principles don't go through. As for the statement made in this article about Maori protecting fish, what about the animals they made extincted like the Moe bird. My family intend to leave if they don't get to vote on the principles, I expect personally a mass exodus which will hit the economy even more. 

Up
0

Unsure that NZ Issues is gives us much of a clue on public opinions. It will be a shame to see you leave, but there will be no mass exodus. 

Up
0

On Nozick, his Entitlement Theory does include a third principle of rectification of injustice. 

Up
0

I think Brian Easton describes anything he doesn't like as neo liberal. 

In reality ACT has not really argued in favour of market forces for property.  Their existence in parliament is dependent on protecting the rights of 'green leafy suburbs in Auckland' to avoid the Government's previous attempts at removing zoning to ensure medium density. They believe in reducing Government government regulation, except where it impacts the rights of white wealthy home owners.

Up
0

This actual version the 2nd article may help. Other versions opens up a can of worms.

English version.

"Her Majesty the Queen of England confirms and guarantees to the Chiefs and Tribes of
New Zealand and to the respective families and individuals thereof the full exclusive and
undisturbed possession of their Lands and Estates Forests Fisheries and other properties
which they may collectively or individually possess so long as it is their wish and desire
to retain the same in their possession; but the Chiefs of the United Tribes and the individual
Chiefs, yield to Her Majesty the exclusive right of Preemption over such lands as the
proprietors thereof may be disposed to alienate at such prices as may be agreed upon between
the respective Proprietors and persons appointed by Her Majesty to treat with them in that behalf."

re-posted from another article and commentator.

https://www.bassettbrashandhide.com/post/dr-lawrie-knight-fact-checking…

 

Up
0