sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Susan St John says the issue of whether the NZ Super Fund should pay tax is largely one of smoke and mirrors

Public Policy / opinion
Susan St John says the issue of whether the NZ Super Fund should pay tax is largely one of smoke and mirrors
taxrf2.jpg
Source: 123rf.com

By Susan St John*

The NZ Super Fund (NZSF) was set up in 2001, a time when the government had spare money from budget surpluses. The intent was to tax smooth the future costs of the universal NZ Super by paying a bit more today, to pay a bit less tomorrow.  Certainly, the NZSF has performed well enough but it is no magic bullet. 

Internationally, the NZSF is unusual, Sovereign wealth funds in other countries are generally based on revenue from real resources like North Sea Oil in Norway and invested for the overall good of the country. In contrast, original contributions to the NZ Super Fund were made from budget surpluses, or excess tax revenue. Today there are no budget surpluses therefore contributions must be borrowed. Either way, there is no free lunch. Putting excess tax revenue into the fund is at the expense of other things we need such as more doctors and nurses, educational needs and less poverty.   Alternatively, the increase in public debt constrains other useful capital spending that for example could help us prepare for the explosion in demands for healthcare as the older population ages.  

The NZ Super Fund is often misinterpreted to mean we will be able to afford higher pension costs as the population over 65 grows. But it does not reduce the cost of NZ Super at all. If the parameters like the age of entitlement, level of pension, and universality do not change, the pressure of the ageing population on scarce resources will be unaffected even when there are withdrawals from the fund.

A complex formula for the amount taxpayers provide each year is explained in a highly technical paper- the Golden Years by Treasury’s Matthew Bell. The latest projections from Budget 2024 show that contributions will be made to the fund for the next ten years and after that payments will dribble out of the fund until about 2060 when they become more significant. Even at the peak in the 2080s, withdrawals are about only 15% of the total cost of net NZ Super. The fund never runs down and will be a massive size by the end of the century.

There are some fundamental unanswered questions about the fund, its purpose, what it is invested in, and its opportunity costs. In the current climate it is easier to be distracted into minor issues such as whether the fund should pay tax.

Currently the Govt is considering  not taxing NZSF. No tax sounds appealing and certainly may simplify life for the Superfund Guardians as the tax calculations on different investments can be onerous. But retirees and savers will not be magically better off with no consequences elsewhere for the government's budget. The loss of this tax revenue for example would enlarge the budget deficit.

The issue of whether the NZSF should pay tax is largely one of smoke and mirrors. Under the formula, if NZSF retains tax in the fund, government would simply be required to contributes less when the fund is building up. Thus, the lower contribution offsets the government's loss of tax revenue. Likewise, when the fund is drawn down, those payments back to the state are larger, and act to offset the tax loss.

As Matthew Bell says in Golden Years

…the overall outcomes for the NZSF, in terms of receiving funds from, and returning funds to, the government, is not markedly different over the long term, whether the Fund pays tax or is tax exempt.

Therefore it is hard to know why Minister Simon Watts said a possible tax exemption for the Fund “could free up more funds for retirement savings”.

There have been suggestions that if the tax is removed from the NZSF then KiwiSaver should also be tax exempt and that would be good thing by encouraging people to save more for their own retirement.

It is one thing to make the NZ SF tax exempt as a fund owned by us all collectively and another to bring back the old traditional tax treatment of private saving for retirement. The reason we got rid of those tax incentives in the late 1980s was sound: the benefits of tax concessions went largely to high income savers and high wealth people. The same would be true today; it would be a backward and very costly step. The current modest state subsidies for KiwiSaver are well designed, don’t favour the rich, and could be expanded at far lower cost.

There is a nice consistency at the moment whereby the NZ Super Fund and KiwiSaver funds are treated much the same for tax purposes. The urgent need to align the tax treatment of housing to match investments in these funds is more worthy of government attention.  


*Susan St John is Honorary Associate Professor, Economic Policy Centre, Auckland Business School, at the University of Auckland.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

10 Comments

But what will that forward proxy buy?

In 2030?

In 2040?

In 2050? 

I look at the World3 graphic (BAU or Herrington's BAU2) and thnk the proxy will be worthless. Indeed, we're fooling ourselves the way workers in a dying business are, when they accept shares in lieu of wages...

Up
1

No tax on Kiwisaver.  At entry, during or exit.  It's not a financial device, it's a social instrument.

We can phase National Super out as we phase Kiwisaver in.

Up
5

I had Kiwisaver and when I retired I spent it. Not much - less than a boss would have made but more than a street cleaner would have saved.

Now I live on Super and it is fair - same amount whether I own my house or not, work or not, and it is not influenced by my being an immigrant only 20 years ago.

Up
0

TBF Kiwisaver is so relatively young that at most you likely had your annual salary in your account, whereas the amount people have at retirement is going to exponentially increase over the next 25-30 years as people have been in it for longer. To the point where people will reach 65 and could have (very roughly) 10-12x their salary in Kiwisaver. 

Not taxing it could incentivise this to be even higher but we need to look at who can then access Super (particularly as any tax incentive would proportionately benefit higher income earners) as this lower tax should come with the benefit of not having to provide universal Super. 

Up
1

We need to reintroduce the surcharges.

Up
1

Phase out National Super entirely.  In steps.  Gone by 2050.

Up
0

Yes, we need to bring back the surcharge abolished in 1998, or something like it, to keep NZ Super viable by ensuring it goes to those who need it.
https://www.auckland.ac.nz/assets/business/about/our-research/research-…

Up
0

Whats not discussed is what should the Super funds be invested in?

If we setup an infrastructure fund which kiwisaver funds and the Super fund could invest in they could then fund infrastructure in NZ - sure they need to be paid for this but so does debt borrowed to build it. The positive is the repayments go to NZers. Roads, Ferry terminals that then charge ship operators to use.

I wouldn't want to see it all invested here by any stretch but it then frees the Government up to concentrate on other things we want funded just for the public good.

We only need to look at Australia with Super funds of over 4 trillion now - what would have been if Muldoon had not canned it in the 1970s - but its never to late.

Up
0

'We only need to look at Australia with Super funds of over 4 trillion now - what would have been if Muldoon had not canned it in the 1970s - but its never to late"

Whenever i see this argument i ask why does Australia have all of the same problems that we do?

Up
0

Susan St John writes:
'There have been suggestions that if the tax is removed from the NZSF then KiwiSaver should also be tax exempt and that would be good thing by encouraging people to save more for their own retirement.
'It is one thing to make the NZ SF tax exempt as a fund owned by us all collectively and another to bring back the old traditional tax treatment of private saving for retirement. The reason we got rid of those tax incentives in the late 1980s was sound: the benefits of tax concessions went largely to high income savers and high wealth people. The same would be true today; it would be a backward and very costly step. The current modest state subsidies for KiwiSaver are well designed, don’t favour the rich, and could be expanded at far lower cost.
'There is a nice consistency at the moment whereby the NZ Super Fund and KiwiSaver funds are treated much the same for tax purposes. The urgent need to align the tax treatment of housing to match investments in these funds is more worthy of government attention.'

I wonder what Susan St John thinks of Andrew Coleman's recent argument for introducing a compulsory-contribution KiwiSaver 2.0 that, if implemented now, would have people who were able to save cover their own retirement for the decade from age 65 till 75, when NZ Super would kick in; and whether such a scheme would be viable if it followed the existing TTE regime instead of the EET that Coleman proposes.

Up
0