sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

Andrew Coleman compares and contrasts pay-as-you-go funded pensions to save-as-you-go funded pensions, touching on what a change in New Zealand might mean

Public Policy / opinion
Andrew Coleman compares and contrasts pay-as-you-go funded pensions to save-as-you-go funded pensions, touching on what a change in New Zealand might mean
bath

By Andrew Coleman*

Between 1975 and 1977, New Zealand scrapped the compulsory saving scheme that was introduced in August 1974 and adopted what is now the most unusual retirement income and tax policies in the OECD. It is becoming increasingly obvious that this system has problems. To mark the 50th anniversary of the compulsory saving scheme, this series of articles re-examines whether New Zealand’s retirement income policies could be modified or redesigned to better suit the 21st century.

Pay-as-you-go and save-as-you-go retirement income schemes

The welfare and contributory pensions that most older people in OECD countries receive from governments differ significantly in terms of their philosophy and delivery mechanisms, but both can be organised on either a pay-as-you-go or a save-as-you-go basis. If a country has a welfare-based system organised on a pay-as-you-go basis, the taxes that are collected are immediately paid out as pensions and nothing is saved. This is largely what happens in New Zealand. If the same system were funded on a save-as-you-go basis, the taxes that are collected would be accumulated in a sovereign wealth fund and invested before the pensions are paid out at a subsequent date.

Whether a pension is operated on a pay-as-you-go or save-as-you-go basis is an “under the hood” issue that is often ignored. But just as the engine of a car affects its performance and fuel economy, pension schemes run on a pay-as-you-go basis and pension schemes run on a save-as-you-go-basis have very different consequences. They affect the overall structure of the economy, including the amount of capital people own and the way industry is financed; they affect how much it costs different generations to provide pensions; and they affect the way that the overall costs of a pension scheme are split between different generations. A rule of thumb based on one hundred years’ investment returns is that a pay-as-you-go pension scheme doubles the amount of taxes that people have to pay to get a pension. That is substantial – a bit like the different operating costs of a petrol and an electric car. Most current and future generations of young people would be substantially better off if the government had chosen a save-as-you-go funding system years ago – for instance, in 1977 or 1997, when previous generations voted for New Zealand Superannuation. Young people have inherited a system which is expensive and getting more expensive every year.

In the next three articles I shall examine several differences between save-as-you-go and pay-as-you-go schemes. This article looks at the effect on capital accumulation, while the next one looks at the circumstances where a pay-as-you-go system ends up costing young people much more than a save-as-you-go system. The third one discusses some of the transition difficulties that arise when you attempt to switch from a pay-as-you-go to a save-as-you-go pension scheme. Although this material is not often discussed in New Zealand, it is well established and based on the economic ideas developed in the 1950s and 1960s by four Nobel-prize winning economists, Peter Diamond, Franco Modigliani, Edmund Phelps, and Paul Samuelson. They showed the basic arguments are the same whether a country adopts a welfare-based or a contributory pension scheme, although some details change. Consequently, it is easiest to discuss the case where New Zealand keeps New Zealand Superannuation, but the funding is organised differently.

Save-as-you-go schemes and the 'bathtub' model

A mature government save-as-you-go pension scheme has three parts. The first part is a large government investment fund, like the New Zealand Superannuation Fund, but bigger. The second part is the payments made by young or working-aged people, which are paid into the fund rather than transferred to old people. The third part is the pension payments received by older people in the future. They will still get paid every fortnight, but the pensions are paid from the interest and dividends and profits earned from the investments made by the fund when they paid taxes earlier in their lives, plus some of the capital of the fund.

In some ways the fund can be likened to a big bathtub, with new water pouring in from a “tax-tap” at the top, and old water flowing out from a “pension plughole” at the bottom.  A bathtub does two things. It creates a delay between when the water flows in and when it leaves; and it stores a lot of water. The difference with an investment fund is that the “water” in the “bathtub” expands as it earns interest and profits and dividends, increasing the volume in the tub without putting any more “water” in. The earnings of the fund mean less water needs to flow through the tap for any amount flowing out from the plughole.

A pay-as-you-go system is missing the tub – so it is like a pipe. The water coming out of the tax-tap goes straight out through the pension plughole and there is no chance for it to increase in volume. This doesn’t mean there isn’t a return to the people paying the taxes. If young people are born at a time that there are not very many old people, each person only has to pour a little bit of “tax” into the pipe for each older person to get a generous flow. In contrast, if there are lots of old people around each young person will have to turn the tax-tap up to ‘high’ to generate a sufficiently large flow for all the old people to have enough. This, in a nutshell, is the situation New Zealand increasingly finds itself in.

In contrast to a pay-as-you-go water-pipe, the inflows and outflows of a save-as-you-go system are not meant to be equal all the time. If there are lots of working-age people, the inflows will be greater than the outflows and the fund – the water level in the bathtub - will increase. If there are a small number of working-age people and lots of old people, the fund will decrease. This is the point: once the system matures, each generation will put in an amount that, combined with the interest and dividends and earnings, pays out the pensions they will receive when they are older many years down the track. The system can become intergenerationally neutral, because the amount each generation takes out reflects how much they put in at an earlier stage. This solves some of the problems that arise when generations are different sizes. 

A save-as-you-go pension system accumulates more capital than a pay-as-you-go system – the extra “water” in the tub.  When a government introduces or expands a pay-as-you-go system, saving and capital accumulation decline. The government raises taxes and immediately makes additional payments to retired people – just as if it siphoned off some of the water that was going into the bathtub and diverted it into a pipe. The retired people typically spend rather than save these additional pension payments. Since contemporaneous working-aged people are paying more taxes but are also expecting a larger pension in the future, they typically reduce their private savings and maintain their spending. In total saving decreases and spending increases and less capital is accumulated in the economy.

Of course, the working-age people become retirees in subsequent years. Their pensions enable them to spend, because of the taxes levied on new generations of young people who also have less need for private saving. The process is repeated year after year, and each subsequent generation ends up saving less and accumulating fewer assets. At the economy-wide level, the decline in saving means there is less locally-generated capital to invest in firms or infrastructure or in overseas countries. Unless this capital is fully replaced by foreign-sourced capital, this reduces the earnings of businesses and firms. It also reduces wages, as firms are less productive. 

Something like this happened in New Zealand in 1977, when National Superannuation was introduced, and all people over 60 became entitled to a larger pension. There was an almost immediate decline in the national saving rate. This decline has not been fully reversed, even though the age of eligibility has subsequently been increased, as people are slower to cut consumption when taxes increase than to increase it when taxes decrease.

If New Zealanders had a pension scheme that was based on save-as-you-go funding, the amount of saving and the size of the capital stock would be larger.  This has another implication: it could help in the battle to prevent climate change.  We are all conscious of the rapid progress in solar and wind energy technologies in the last decade, and many more transformational technologies will be developed in the next 50 years. Many of these technologies are capital intensive and will only significantly reduce greenhouse gas emissions if they are implemented on a large scale at home and abroad. This will require large scale saving and investment. The pension funds of many countries already are making green energy investments in less developed countries, to help them increase their energy use without so much coal or gas. Greater domestic savings stemming from a save-as-you-go funded pension scheme will enable New Zealand firms to increase the amount they already invest in these types of projects.

If New Zealand changes from pay-as-you-go funded pensions to save-as-you-go funded pensions, New Zealanders will collectively save more, allowing them to finance some of these green investments and help tackle climate changes issues. More generally, greater capital under the save-as-you-go scheme boosts firm productivity, increasing earnings and wages. This sounds attractive. For young people it has another benefit – under many circumstances a save-as-you-go system can cost less, much less, than a pay-as-you-go system. This topic is tackled next week.


*This series and an accompanying paper are based on work I started in 2020 with Jeanne-Marie Bonnet while we were both at the University of Otago. I am very grateful for her assistance and insights. All errors remain my own.

(This article is part 3 in the series. Part 1 is here, and part 2 is here).

**Andrew Coleman is a visiting professor at the Asia School of Business. This article is his personal view of retirement policy in New Zealand, based on academic study.

Coleman is on extended leave from the Reserve Bank of New Zealand, while working overseas. The views expressed in this article do not represent the RBNZ and are unrelated to work conducted at the Bank, which has no responsibility for retirement policy in New Zealand.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

15 Comments

It's too late to change the model now. The demographics are all wrong for that.

Recent govts have cranked up immigration in an attempt to mitigate this but its not working due to all the young people leaving and these young people bringing in lots of ill old people in subsequent years.

Plus NZ is not a country where there will be a big windfall. Like in Oz with its mineral boom.

Up
4

It's definitely hard to see how the population can even afford it's existing liabilities, let alone also set aside enough to fund future retirement needs.

Up
2

Its ok they are hoping to sell their house for millions and downsize... all at the same relative time... perhaps with a shrinking population

Up
1

The universal pension introduced by Robert Muldoon in 1977 was his great contribution to New Zealand, or rather, to New Zealanders. It was the last echo of the cradle-to-the-grave social welfare that the first Labour government tried to introduce between 1935 and 1949. It survives today, diminished, as NZ Superannuation.

Its great flaw is that it is funded by current taxation. Inevitably that must continue. But for NZ Superannuation to succeed in the future, contributions to the NZ Superannuation Fund must be greatly increased. It must become New Zealand's sovereign wealth fund.

There are two changes that ought to be made immediately:

(1) the NZSF must cease paying tax on its earnings. It is absurd that the Government each year puts money into the fund, then takes it out as tax.

(2) The state subsidy of $521 a year payable to people who contribute to their private KiwiSaver funds should cease. This money should be going into the NZSF to benefit everybody equally, in the future. KiwiSaver divides the haves, who have the surplus income to save for their future, and the have-nots, who must spend every dollar simply to survive and cannot save. The state subsidy to private KiwiSaver accounts increases the gulf between haves and have-nots; the same money invested in the NZSF would promise equal disbursement to all in retirement.

These two steps are but the beginning of the increased funding needed for superannuation, for it is not only future superannuation that needs to be funded by way of the NZSF.

The present super rates are manifestly inadequate. When Muldoon introduced his pension fund in 1977, the married rate was 80% of the full-time average wage, and the single rate 60% of that. This proved unaffordable, especially so after 1984 and the reduction in income tax rates. The super payout was reduced and a surcharge imposed on those who had other income. That was abolished in 1998, guaranteeing future unaffordability of superannuation.

The single-person-living-alone rate today is $521.62 a week after tax. The Massey University Financial Education Centure publishes annually an estimate of how much a person in retirement needs to live on. It gives figures for how much a person needs to live on with 'no frills' if they live in the city ('metro'), and in the provinces. It also gives higher figures for retirement 'with choices'. The figures Massey gives for June 2023, when the single-living-alone super rate was $496.37 a week, were $826.26 a week for a 'no-frills' metro existence, and $689.54 a week for a provincial 'no frills' existence.

https://www.massey.ac.nz/documents/1554/new-zealand-retirement-expendit…

In 2024 the $496.37 super rate has become $521.62 a week after tax. Applying the same factor, the Massey figures would now be $868.23 a week for a 'no frills' 'metro' retirement, and $724.57 for the provincial. (Weekly after-tax rates for a full-time worker now are: minimum $785, living $928, median $1034.)

The point I'm laboriously getting to is that NZ Superannuation is not enough to live on, either now or in the future. We need more funds both for the NZSF to provide for the future, but to boost superannuation to an adequate level now. I see headlines today that property owners have increased their wealth by $500 billion in the past 20 years.It would be unreasonable to increase income tax on wages to boost super now as well as invest in the NZSF for the future. The obvious source to tap is the unearned wealth of property value gains. New Zealand needs to reintroduce inheritance taxes and gift taxes, and it needs to reintroduce land taxes and impose capital gains taxes. Or it could explore the Fair Economic Return tax proposed by Susan St John and Terry Baucher:

https://www.auckland.ac.nz/assets/business/our-research/docs/economic-p…

The other thing that governments must agree to do is to reimpose a form of the surtax on other income that was abolished in 1998. NZ Super as it stands is not enough for those  who need it (as the Massey figures above argue), but too much for those who don't need it. If super were to be increased to at least the $727.57-a-week no frills provincial rate from $521.62 for the single person living alone, with other rates increased in proportion, it would be vastly overpaying people who had other incomes as well.

Susan St John, again, has proposed a solution, though the taxation rates would have to be much more severe if the super rate were raised:

https://www.auckland.ac.nz/assets/business/about/our-research/research-…

Up
2

KiwiSaver divides the haves, who have the surplus income to save for their future, and the have-not

Could you elaborate on this? Given theres a minimum of 3% to put in, I struggle so see why you mention surplus income, although I appreciate that there’s many who choose never to sign up to kiwisaver to their own detriment.

Up
2

There are people who don't have any money left at the end of each week. They are unlikely to save in kiwisaver if they are struggling to just get by. 3% is a surplus, even if it is small.

Up
2

This is true, however across my lifetime thus far the majority of people I've ever met who aren't in kiwisaver or pulled out, is more due to the perceived waste of piling money into something they didn't understand more so than being in genuine need of the 3%. Notwithstanding today may be different with the cost of living eating away at budgets for necessities. I've also spoken to a couple of financial advisors in passing who have reiterated that they are genuinely shocked at the number of people who aren't in kiwisaver, simply from lack of knowledge of it and hence never registering.

Up
1

I withdraw my kiwsaver as a FHB 6 years ago. Since then i have purchased two IP's and have no plans to ever contribute to kiwisaver in the future. Surplass  income goes into savings on an offset mortgage or occasionally to Rat poison, i fully understand that the keys to kiwisaver is held by someone elese, i would much rather the security of holding the keys to my own savings and having it liquid should i wish to use it.

Up
0

See the box chart towards end of article. NZ Super is $21.6 billion, and growing rapidly.

This box is bigger than all of education.

ALL OF EDUCATION!

Our priorities are wrong.

https://www.rnz.co.nz/news/in-depth/518245/budget-2024-in-charts-what-d…

Up
2

Also over 2/3 the cost of the entire health budget, both of which are due to grow in the coming decade substantially.

Up
3

Mining royalties should be 50% and paid into a sovereign wealth fund. KiwiSaver must be compulsory at a rate of 10%. A generation has wasted wealth buying and selling houses of one another to the benefit of the Aussie banks.

Up
2

Good article cheers.

Up
0

Means test the pension. No pension for those over 65's who are still working. Stop parliamentary and judges pensions too.

 

Up
1

I think you will find a lot of people are still working over 65 because they cant to live on their miserable pension and still paying a reasonable amount of tax whe working. You need 65k per year to live a reasonable retired life in NZ  and you get 41555.00 after tax ,do the math

Up
1

Means and asset testing. We have a situation today where low paid workers are kindly providing for pensioners living in multi-million dollar homes, so that they don't have to move or draw on their equity and can pass the whole lot onto their already privileged children.  

Up
0