sign up log in
Want to go ad-free? Find out how, here.

The New Zealand Tax Podcast; The calm before the storm? The tax wedge increases for workers. And more from the Titans of Tax

Public Policy / analysis
The New Zealand Tax Podcast; The calm before the storm? The tax wedge increases for workers. And more from the Titans of Tax
tax


It has been a quiet week in the tax world, which, to be honest, is quite welcome. But there's also a growing sense of a calm before the storm, that being the Coalition government's first Budget on 30th May. I'll offer up some speculation as to what I think will be in the budget closer to the time, but one thing we do know will be is expected to happen is adjustments to the fat tax thresholds, which as listeners will well be aware of, have not actually been adjusted since October 2010.

It so happened last week the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (the OECD) released Taxing Wages 2024, its annual Taxing Wages report. This is a fascinating document which looks across the composition of wages and provides details of taxes paid on wages. This year, it's also focusing on fiscal incentives for second earners in the OECD and how tax policy might contribute to gender outcome gaps and labour out market outcomes. It’s a big report which runs to 679 pages and is only available online.

Taxes are increasing thanks to inflation

One of the things that comes out of the Executive Summary was that in the words of the report tax systems in the OECD are not fully adjusting to inflation. Consequently,

“The average tax wedge for all eight household types covered in this report increased in the majority of countries between 2022. And 2023 driven in most cases by higher income tax. For the second consecutive year, more post tax incomes at the average wage level declined across the majority of all OECD countries now.”

The tax wedge is described as the difference between the labour costs to and an employer and the corresponding net take home pay of the employee. It represents the sum of the total personal income tax and Social Security contributions paid by employees and employers. Less any cash benefits that the employee might receive.

New Zealand has consistently scored well in this measure because we don't have Social Security taxes and we'll talk a little bit more about that later. But notwithstanding that, the average take home wage for New Zealand employees has been declining over the past few years.

The report has an appendix showing the evolution of effective tax rates on labour since 2000 with a number of separate measurements based on single persons, single parents, or married couple with two children. It looks at what the tax wedge for each group is based on 67% of average wage, 100% of average wage and 167% of the average wage.

Now, whatever measure you take, you can see that the tax burden for New Zealand employees has been rising steadily since 2010, but you can see it start to accelerate in the last three to four years. So, for a single person at 167% of the average wage, their tax burden has gone from 23.9% in 2017 to 25.8% in 2024. Now you might think 2 percentage points isn’t much, but it becomes more noticeable as it accumulates over time. For a single person at 100% of the average wage the tax burden has gone from 18.3% to 21.1% over the same period.

This OECD report reinforces what we've been saying for some time that tax adjustments to the thresholds are long overdue. Now those who listened in to last week's podcast with Sir Rob, Rob McLeod, Robin Oliver and Geof Nightingale will have noted pretty much everyone was of the view that the threshold where the 30% tax rate kicks in, that's $48,000 was a major problem in our tax system. Geof was particularly insistent on this point. This OECD data reinforces that point. So, it will be interesting to see what moves are made in that space in the Budget at the end of the month.

Social security taxes – time for a rethink?

Moving on, thanks to everyone who's commented or given feedback here and across the various social media platforms about last week’s podcast. It's always great to have some engagement. I do read all the comments even if I don't always respond.

There were some particularly interesting comments from Andrew Coleman of the University of Otago about Social Security taxes and the absence of them in New Zealand. As he noted New Zealand is an outlier in world terms in this respect.

Now, as I mentioned in the podcast, Social Security contributions were once quite a significant factor of the New Zealand tax system from the 1930s until the 1960s. But what happened over time was that the contributions weren't hypothecated and applied only to Social Security payments, but in fact just became treated as part of taxation generally until in April 1964, the Social Security Fund was merged into the Consolidated Fund

Ultimately, the then Finance Minister Robert Muldoon decided in 1968 that separate Social Security contributions were no longer required and merged everything formally into income tax. Since then period, income tax has used to pay for Social Security such as welfare and superannuation.

That's more than 50 years ago, but as Doctor Coleman pointed out many other countries have Social Security taxes. So, is that something we should consider in more detail? Well, I hope to explore that point in a separate podcast.

***

Sir Rob McLeod, Robin Oliver and Geof Nightingale on expanding the tax base

[In this part of the podcast I asked Sir Rob, Robin and Geof about the strains New Zealand’s Broad Base Low-Rate approach is experiencing and if a government wanted to raise how would it do so- through a wealth tax, capital gains tax, stamp duties or estate duties, whatever].

Sir Rob Mcleod (RM)
Well, if I can kick off, I'm a huge fan of Broad Base Low-Rate (BBLR). I think it's got a very simple thrust. It's as much about pragmatism as it is about technical. I think we need to be careful in my experience with the debate and understanding that a Broad Base Low-Rate system is not one characterised by a myriad of taxes. Some people interpret a myriad of taxes as achieving breadth and therefore fitting with Broad Base Low-Rate. No, my definition of Broad Base Low-Rate is a few taxes with a broad reach. That's where you get the simplicity. And the income tax and the GST covers most of GDP in the nation.

What does it not touch is the question to ask. You can talk about wealth tax and CGT, capital gains tax, but they're actually part of the income tax. There's an overlap between wealth tax, capital gains tax and the income tax. I don't believe that that gap justifies the kind of emphasis that's being given to wealth tax and CGT.

Sure, we've got some capital gains not taxed, most of them actually are taxed already in the system. The comprehensive capital gains tax I think in that sense is a bit of a misnomer because we do not have comprehensive taxation in the New Zealand system. And if you go and then put wealth taxes on, whether it be land or wealth in general, you are actually doubling up on the income tax. You've got an element of double tax in doing that and that takes us back to the starting point, that Broad Base Low-Rate is about identifying the gaps. And there's bugger all gaps actually left by a broadly designed GST and income tax such as New Zealand has.

And when we go into the debates on specifics around the margins of that base, there are good reasons for arguing about why we shouldn't have them. So that's why I think BBLR is there. If you want to get more out of what we've got than the broad base of income tax and GST, you’ve got to justify it and you've got to start with what percentage of the GDP should be taxed in the first place. With balanced budgets, government spending equals taxation. With a balanced budget, which is kind of where the world wants to be these days.

So, I think recognise that the tax rate for the nation is government spending divided by GDP. And there's a hell of a lot of benefit from there. So, if you want a tax cut, you’ve got to cut the government spending.  It's the only way to do it. Those various elements I think are very interconnected in the debate around Broad Base Low-Rates.

Geof Nightingale (GN)
I think your question was where would you go to for another 1% of GDP? And I would agree with Rob that it feels to me that 30% of GDP or Government expenditure to GDP at roughly 30% has (that’s our long-run average, it spikes up and down for pandemics and earthquakes and recessions and things) that's a constraint that I would be quite personally happy  for our economy to operate against.

The question is then how you raise that revenue. And I totally support Broad Base Low-Rate. I think it's effective in practise and 30 years of experience. I think the missing bit still there is our income tax is not as Broad Based as it should be, and I think we do need to extend it into further realised capital gains. So, whether you do that as a separate comprehensive capital gains tax like other countries, or you just change the definition of income, that's a design feature.

Philosophically, it's the same thing. It's just how you get there. Taxing more income through realised capital gains, and then I would recycle that revenue into tax cuts, reductions, initially in  the lower marginal rates because that's where our problems come with high effective marginal tax rates in conjunction with welfare, which leads to productivity and incentives to work and all of that. So I would extend the taxation of capital, recycle the revenue and like Rob aim for 30% government expenditure over GDP.

TB
Robin, you were part of the tax working group,  you were one of the three dissenters in 2019. I that still your opinion?

Robin Oliver (RO)
As Rob said and Geof echoed, it's not a black and white issue. Do you tax capital gains or not? I mean, Michael Cullen kept on trying to make the point, talking about taxing capital income, not capital gains. Everybody ignored it, but he had a point that we do tax capital gains in certain cases and it's all part of our income tax system and GST anyway. Are there holes in the system where you can efficiently raise more money at low cost?  And the big hole, the gap in our system, it came out in the tax working group and all other reports is land.

We are a growing economy, growing population, land rises/increases systematically in value and that produces a lot of income and overall, we don't tax it. You look at all the data, you know, higher wealth people, predominantly own land. Not all, but predominantly. So OK, should we be taxing land in one form or another? And I've got sympathy for that, but you're going down to the workability. No government will ever tax home ownership. If it does, it will cease to be a government pretty quickly and someone sensible will come in and abolish that tax. So that's a big hole in any land base. And then you've got issues about iwi and their relationship with land. You've got farmers.

We used to have a land tax. We had a comprehensive tax in the 1890s and we ended up with a tax just on Queen St commercial property. Everybody else got exemptions over time. I have some sympathy for taxing the increase in the value of land or land in some form which is not taxed now, but the housing, the home ownership stuff. You know, David Caygill, he proposed taxing homeowners. And he got told to back off.

I was working with him on capital gains tax proposal and we officials recommended including home ownership. And we were gobsmacked, totally bewildered when he accepted our recommendation. We expected him not to. And he went off to lose that next election, but probably not for that reason.

Workability matters. Home ownership is off the table. Our problem as a country is we take our savings, we invest it in land, we borrow from Australia, we invest in more land, bid up the price of land. We end up with the same amount of land as we began with - because that doesn't increase - and heavily in debt to Australian banks. Solving that problem is not easy.

The problem with overinvestment in housing

TB
Yes, it's a behavioural impact.  I had this conversation with an American client yesterday, who because of the fact they have to file U.S. tax returns, they're subject to capital gains tax. But the FIF regime, he looked at that, and said, well, I can't invest in stocks so I'm going to look at residential investment property here. That's really a case of an unintended consequence of a tax.

On the family home, I fully grasp all of that, but is there an argument for saying that there is a limit? Because we build some of the biggest houses in the world. New Zealand houses - new houses, were until quite recently - are the third largest in the OECD. They were nearly getting on for close to 200 square metres.

RO
We like our houses.

TB
So could you say above two and a half million dollars or $5 million, the gain above that - some pro rata, we’re getting into technical details, but there is this thing that you've just espoused it perfectly, Robin. That at present we're encouraged to invest in land and more land and borrow. So, there's a loss of productivity, that 20% dead weight. There's got to be a lot of lost productivity because capital is diverted into land rather than elsewhere.

RO
The current group did look at something like that, although it was outside our terms of reference. We were not allowed to even consider the home or the land underneath the home or the sky above the. In terms of reference that we did look at that. The trouble is, a $2,000,000 house is not all that much in Auckland, as Michael Cullen kept on putting out, it was a hell of a lot in Whakatane.

TB
There are 77,000 homes in Auckland worth more than $2,000,000, according to an OIA I got.

RO
Probably one in Whakatane.

GN
There's a technical solution. If you were going to put all realised capital gains into the tax pot, you give every New Zealander a lifetime exemption, regardless of asset class or description, and that might be $5,000,000 or more, less but and that then shouldn't distort behaviour. It’s arguably equitable and from a compliance and administration perspective,  it would take probably 95% of us out of the of the loop.

RO
And with that 95% of revenue.

GN
Yes, well, maybe not because the assets are weighted towards the top. But anyway, the argument against that was always administrative. It's very difficult to administer. But with current digitisation and things, I'm not sure those administration and compliance arguments - the integration of the land registers and share registers and things - as strong as it used to be. So, there are theoretical solutions there, but they're hard to get to the public.

RO
The idea of taxing the person with over $5 million has got a lot of appeal, but it's not realistic.  I always give the example of the idea you can freely tax all these very high wealth individual/ medium wealth individual people. Well, some of those are your medical specialists, your surgeon, your oncologist. And they can go to Australia.

You whack this $5,000,000 tax on their income over a lifetime and off they go to Sydney. So you're sitting here in New Zealand, you've got cancer or something like that, and we’ve got a more equal society, but we have no treatment for cancer.  Off to a hospice you go.

GN
That might be the case with a wealth tax, but with an income tax I'm not convinced, Robin. I mean, Rob might be able to comment with direct experience of working in Australia. But labour and consumption taxes in Australia on high earners, medical professionals, they're pretty tough compared to New Zealand. (TB 45% top rate plus 2% Medicare).I would have thought, but I don't know what your experience is Rob.

RM
it's not just Australia, we're becoming more global, aren't we? So almost every country is a neighbour of one sort or another these days. The other thing is these people are incentivised to find these loopholes. And having lived, having operated and worked in Australia for six years, they've seen wealthy people find loopholes there too.  So that that won't go away.

TB
It's our job to find them, to be frank.

RM
Yes.

RO
The government legislates for them. You get tax free superannuation in Australia, or 15%. We've got to get away from this idea we can tax our wealth. Our problem is, as we're next to Australia, is Australia becoming wealthier than we are. It's attracting our nurses, our doctors, our policemen, our police persons and what have you through higher wages.  We've got to increase our wage level and our productivity, and we don't do that by sitting around and inventing new taxes.

TB
But do we change the incidence of tax, so that capital gets diverted into more productive areas?

RO
I give you the example of houses. I agree with that.

GN
Our effective marginal tax rates, in those doctors, nurses and policemen, if you go across to Australia and look at those, yes, the incomes are definitely higher 30 or 40%. But I think there's a tax dynamic in there as well for those people. Because we're sweating our labour incomes, particularly in those low ends.

Robin has often said this, the worst tax rate we've got in New Zealand is the 30% rate at $48,000.  Which is huge, it kicks in below the median income.  So, I think there's a tax dynamic in those migrations of doctors, nurses and police as well.

What about inheritance taxes?

TB
The $48,000 threshold is a shocker. A final point on this housing. I think you're right, politically a capital gains that incorporates the family home is impossible. You're not even a one term government with that. But does that perhaps point to the need - and this is where the IMF come in - is that maybe that's picked up through an inheritance tax at a separate point.  Inheritance taxes, estate duty used to be quite significant. It was 5% of government revenue way back when in 1949, and they were one of the first taxes we introduced here. But they've declined over time around the world, but now there seems to be particularly with this, the wealthiest generation in history - and I think all of us are members of the Boomers -  are starting to pass away, and there's a huge transfer of wealth about to happen. And governments are looking at that.

RM
Can I bring the conversation back to where I was about what percentage of GDP should tax be.

Because we are straight into, in essence, the tapestry of taxes. And what lurks underneath the motive for that conversation is really redistribution. Because a lot of the motive in the conversation that we're having is about getting feathers off particular geese, and about certain thresholds and the rest of it.

The starting point ultimately is what does the country need by way of revenue as a percentage of GDP now? Now, if you're arguing that actually New Zealand's got a big problem of injustice or inequity because the rich are basically getting away with it, is a bit of a different to back from where we came from and earlier on in our conversation. Geof, to be fair, has identified redistribution as a goal. So he's been consistent in that regard.

But I think this demonstrates why it's so important to first of all ask yourself what you're trying to do with your tax system, and if it is about revenue and getting a particular percentage of the GDP, then I think that these debates about estate duty and wealth tax and land tax are red herrings.

The 1% of GDP, for example, Geof, that you've mentioned in the question we’re asked to consider through a new tax, does not undermine my general principle of the broad reach and impact of GST and income tax. In fact, you guys (Robin and Geof) were both on the Cullen Review and you actually, in the report that came out, compared a 1% increase in GST with the capital gains tax and it kind of blew it away. That demonstrates my point that the Broad Base reach of GST and income tax can do everything that you're trying to get out of these, peripheral and miscellaneous taxes. The only thing that’s left standing as to why you want to do it, is redistribution.

RO
I'm OK with that, obviously. But getting on to death duties, estate duties,  they have an interesting history. Other countries have them. People have different ideas about bequests and motivation. You know, how important it is to give money to the children. You've got Warren Buffett, who honestly gave each of his children 10 million and that's it. Well, 10 million seems like a nice little nest egg, but in Warren Buffett's terms, that's just rounding. Bugger all in bequest terms, Other people will die for it. Literally, they will fight. It is enormously powerful. They will do anything to avoid death duties.

When we used to have them, that was the area of massive tax planning. It was the beginning of it all - avoiding death duties was a massive industry. And you think it’d be easy to do. Well, you've got to have gift duties as well, otherwise people just give it away to the kids. And you end up with Inland Revenue, as it used to do, roaring around, stamping every gift that's made in the country, every Christmas and what have you, and determining they're not subject to gift duty.

Massive amounts of bureaucracy involved. They are not easy taxes and I’ll just finish with the history of the end of death duties in New Zealand.

It started off with Australia.  Death duties were limited to the state governments. When Queensland got rid of its death duties Victoria and New South Wales and the rest of Australia followed suit. We followed thereafter. Because anybody was going to go to the country which didn't have it.

Death duties have got some appeal to people, I understand the issues. It’s very appealing when people don't have any bequest, motive to actually tax a windfall gain. The only reason they are working, building their business is for the children and grandchildren. These people will react massively to its reintroduction.

[This is an edited part of the full podcast which readers are encouraged to download and listen to at the link at the top of this page.]

On that note, that’s all for this week, I’m Terry Baucher and you can find this podcast on my website www.baucher.tax or wherever you get your podcasts.  Thank you for listening and please send me your feedback and tell your friends and clients. Until next time, kia pai to rā. Have a great day.

We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.

Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.

30 Comments

"For a nation to try to tax itself into prosperity is like a man standing in a bucket and trying to lift himself up by the handle." Winston Churchill 

"The question is not what anybody deserves. The question is who is to take on the God-like role of deciding what everybody else deserves. You can talk about 'social justice' all you want. But what death taxes boil down to is letting politicians take money from widows and orphans to pay for goodies that they will hand out to others, in order to buy votes to get re-elected. That is not social justice or any other kind of justice."

Thomas Sowell

Up
6

Yes, not sure why we've allowed the entitled to set up NZ society as one that taxes from the productive working folk and transfers wealth to property speculators by carrying them tax-wise, subsidising them, and bailing them out in hard times. Seems rather unjustly harsh on the widows and orphans of NZ.

Winston Churchill said it right:

Roads are made, streets are made, services are improved, electric light turns night into day, water is brought from reservoirs a hundred miles off in the mountains -- and all the while the landlord sits still. Every one of those improvements is effected by the labour and cost of other people and the taxpayers.

We can't tax the working folk and carry the land speculators and expect prosperity.

Up
2

As is stated in the podcast, a wealth tax is a doubling up of income tax.  It would violate many of New Zealand's international tax treaties.  Labour and the Greens have never even considered this.  The U.S. Internal Revenue Service has stated that under the NZ/US treaty on double taxation, New Zealand can tax income from the U.S. only once. 

Up
1

So if that money is spent in NZ, we aren't allowed to charge GST? I hope no-one tells the US. 

Up
3

Well technically the GST is rolled up into the price, so a bit like claiming they're double taxed because the business includes a portion of rates, PAYE etc into the sell price.

 

Up
0

This is not actually true. We don't get anything back in return for the GST that is added to the price of a purchase. Other "markups" are the seller's reward for the service he provides in running a supermarket, shop, or whatever.

Up
0

I’m no expert and as such am preparing for public ridicule of the following:

Would a CGT on the family home and other assets be more acceptable to kiwis if we allowed for the lifetime cost of interest for debt funding that asset to be ring fenced and deducted from the gain before tax? 

Double deduction rules would be needed:
for rentals or dividends on stocks bought with debt that deduct interest you would not be able to double deduct at the time of realised gains.

Example: i buy a home worth $1m. I have debt of $800k. Over 10 years the home appreciates by $630k (5%pa). In the same period i paid ~$450k (5%pa while paying principal). 630k - $450k = taxable gain of $180k. 

consider the same scenario but this time i rent the house out for $45k a year. I deduct interest from my earnings and report no income. I sell after 10 years but because i deducted all my interest already i can’t deduct it from the capital gain. I'm taxed the full gain of $630k.
 

i think you could go further here and spread that tax across your income for the time you owned the asset, so add $18k to each years income tax giving you the marginal tax rate advantage, or for simplicity just have CGT at a lower rate to the marginal rate.

Up
2

Add to that inflation indexed value (and maintenance cost?) and the amount of tax collected would be minimal.

Up
1

Maybe, but would enable landlords to deduct expenses and also even the playing field with owner occupiers 

Up
2

A really interesting read. Surprised to discover how well tax experts can express their ideas clearly. For example ""we invest it in land, we borrow from Australia, we invest in more land, bid up the price of land. We end up with the same amount of land as we began with - because that doesn't increase - and heavily in debt to Australian banks."" 

 

Up
9

In NZ we call that wealth creation. It's a good problem to have. 😜

Up
2

It's great! We can live beyond our own productive means by loading up debt for following generations to pay!

There's no such thing as a free lunch, but we get to eat the younger generations' lunch!

Up
3

This finally explains why boomers are so obsessed about what younger generations eat. They don't want to end up stealing avocado on toast, tofu and fake meat washed down by nut milk. 

Up
0

It's wealth transfer rather than wealth creation.

Up
1

Funny too how these tax doyens play down the not inconsiderable role they've played in that.

Up
0

We don't borrow money from Australia though, our banks create it as new deposits. We use NZ Dollars and not AU Dollars.

https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/quarterly-bulletin/2014/q1/money-creati…

Up
0

Land tax is the way. Simple, impossible to avoid, regular, and will tax land speculaton. All reasons why the vested are dead against it.

Up
9

Good to see they think that a realized CGT on all property - including the family home - isn't a bad idea.

But they also escape by saying it would never fly politically (blame transferal?) Surely the solution is simply educating voters why it is a good idea? And why a CGT - once PAYE is adjusted down to compensate - really won't affect most people (except the property barons who have been coining it in for far too long). 

So there's a simple solution ... Get rid of politicians who won't do what needs to be done.

Up
1

It's also a generational unfairness: previous generation got full employment, cheap houses, no CGT and subsequent generation none of that.

Up
1

1990 - Unemployment ~8-9%, Mge interest rate ~15%, House prices dropped ~5%...Good days

Up
0

You omit the golden years preceeding that and the fact unemployment affected more the younger generation (born ~1970). Late boomers to the party. Also even with 15% rates, the overall cost of buying a house was only a few years of income, and a household income was often dad's income, mom staying home.

Housing through the decades, what is affordable? | Newshub

From 1957 to the late 1980s the average New Zealand house price was between two-to-three times the average annual household income.

Then in the 90s (4 in the late 90s)

The average house price had risen to four times the average household income by the late 1990s.

Kiwi households face ongoing affordability squeeze | CoreLogic New Zealand

Mr Davidson said this is an improvement, dropping from a peak of 8.6 in early 2022, however the measure remains above the long-term average for this measure (5.9) as well as the figure of 6.9 in Q3 2023.

Close to 7 in Q3 2023 (after a 8.6 peak early 2022), so yeah, definitely good days.

Up
2

You originally stated "previous generation", not generations. so any "omitting" is not my intention. 

Up
0

Their talk of death duties is extremely misleading. In the past, death duties were a single flat rate and quite punitive. Consequently, escaping them became a big industry. However - I smell a rat.

Does anyone think it's strange that these 3 doyens - who claim to favor of BBLR (Broad Base - Low Rate) taxes don't apply the same logic to any new taxes? Odd ay? Surely they're not influenced by their own income stream?

If one applied their enthusiasm for any new taxes being both broad based and low rate then:

CGT - would be on all property with no exception for the family home (i.e. broad based) and the rate would be tiny, say less than 5%. (i.e. low rate).

Inheritance taxes - would be on all recipients, with no exemptions or thresholds (i.e. broad based), with low rates on the first millions, with steadily climbing rates once up to the 100s of millions, but still lower than they were years ago.

I could go on ...

So why aren't these tax experts applying their own standards to any new taxes?

Surely they haven't become like property owning politicians?

Up
3

How to tax is one thing, how we spend the tax $$ is even more important. 

I wouldn't mind tax man takes all I have as long as I got all I need and want from them. 

 

Up
0

1) 30% of GDP tax rate - The % should be based on a cost benefit assessment not an arbitrary 30%.

2) Optimally how progressive the tax system should be needs to be determined through cost benefit analysis for NZ Inc.

3) Wealth taxes - agree there is not a strong technical argument for them except a) reflect previous capital gains not taxed, b) reflect excess monopoly & oligopoly profits.  The issue is more ensuring the wealth is put to productive use for the NZ economy and the tax structure to incentivize this.

4) Comprehensive capital gains tax is needed.  Capital gains are income and must be taxed, and taxed at the same rate as income.  Almost all the OECD has one.

5) Estate duties / inheritance tax are absolutely needed.  This is income to the recipient and should be taxed.

6) GST should be reduced. Its a regressive tax.

7) The tax take for super needs to be sustainable.  The age of entitlement should be moved up for superannuation but accessible on medical grounds at 65 (there should be no other income).

Also, NZ is running a version of neoliberalism lite with low tax rates that are unsustainable.  The US and UK are already falling to pieces and NZ heading the same way.  We have massive social deficits that can only be addressed through a more progressive tax system and limiting user pays. 

 

Up
3

Capital gains are income and must be taxed, and taxed at the same rate as income. 

Most legal and tax experts seem to be of the opinion that capital gains are not income. Some may regard realised capital gains as income, but this doesn't really make sense since the transaction that gives rise to the gain simply changes the disposition of capital from one asset class to another, i.e. from real estate to cash. Cash is an asset, and though it can result from the earning of income, this not the case when it comes to capital gain.

This does not mean that capital gain should not be taxed, but one would need to find an alternative rationale for doing so. Presumably capital gain might be classed as wealth, but we don't tax wealth either.   

Up
0

Mike you are splitting hairs.

Capital gains should be taxed as income, whether it's on an unrealised or realised basis can be left to each jurisdiction to determine.

Most OECD countries have comprehensive capital gains taxes. There is no reason NZ shouldn't.

 

Up
0

Most OECD countries have comprehensive capital gains taxes. There is no reason NZ shouldn't.

If everybody else went and jumped in the lake, that is no reason why you or I should do so. It is no wonder you cannot appreciate the logic of my argument, and prefer to refer it as "splitting hairs", if you can't understand that. Perhaps you should try to think logically yourself. Logical thought has a lot going for it.

Anyway, I didn't say that capital gains shouldn't be taxed. I merely said that that the argument that it should be taxed because it constitutes income is unsound.

PS: If capital gain was income the IRD would tax it anyway. They wouldn't need any special legislation to do so.

Up
0

The IRD does already tax capital in some cases.

The issue in NZ is that it is not comprehensively taxed.

Thus, as the Tax Working Group showed, investments like property have significant tax advantages over other assets.

The tax playing field is meant to be level so that money flows to where the greatest return is, not where the biggest tax advantage lies.

 

Up
0

That tax wedge is very low for Aotearoa compared to the other countries in the table, and well below the OECD average. 

Are we undertaxed?

Up
0