This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.
Speculative bubbles are common. The Global Financial Crisis of 2008 was an example, as was the New Zealand finance companies’ crash about the same time. The 1987 share market crash was another example, as was the 1929 Wall St Crash. There are at least two major bubbles going on at the moment – one in the crypto-currency market and one in the Chinese Financial System.
Hyman Minsky provided one of the best ways to analyse such bubbles: ‘the financial system swings between robustness and fragility and these swings are an integral part of the process that generates the business cycle’. He thought that such financial instability – and the booms and busts which accompanies it – was inevitable in a so-called ‘free’ market economy, unless government steps in to control through regulation, central bank action and other tools.
His key mechanism that pushes an economy towards a crisis is the accumulation of debt by the non-government sector. There are three types of borrowers that contribute to this debt:
The hedge borrower can make debt payments which cover interest and principal from current cash flows from investments.
For the speculative borrower, the cash flow from investments can cover the interest due, but the borrower must regularly roll over, or re-borrow, the principal.
The Ponzi borrower – named after Charles Ponzi who ran the famous ‘Ponzi scheme’ in 1920 – believes that the appreciation of the value of the asset will be sufficient to refinance the debt because insufficient cash flow from investments; only the appreciating asset value can keep the Ponzi borrower afloat.
These three types of borrowers each dominate in one of Minsky’s three phases of the financial bubble. During the Hedge Phase, banks and borrowers are cautious. Loans are minimal so that borrowers can afford to repay both the initial principal and the interest. It is the ‘Goldilocks’ phase of debt accumulation – ‘not too hot not too cold’.
The Speculative Phase emerges as confidence in the financial system recovers during the Hedge Phase. Borrowers no longer invest on the basis that they can pay both principal and interest. Instead loans are issued for which borrowers can afford to pay only the interest. As the loan principal comes up for payment, they rely on being able to refinance (‘roll over’) their debt, borrowing the principal again. The decline towards financial instability begins.
As confidence continues to grow, investors move into the Ponzi Phase in which they neither pay the interest on the loans nor repay the principal. They rely on the capital appreciation from what they have invested to finance their investing.
The asset-price appreciation that the Ponzi investors rely upon cannot go on forever, especially as it needs to accelerate. Eventually, Stein’s law – if something cannot go on forever, it will stop – takes its toll. Some Ponzi investors withdraw, and there are not enough new investors introducing new cash to fund the withdrawing Ponzi investors.
And so the bubble pops at the ‘Minsky Moment’ after which everyone tries to get out of their investment commitments, turning them back into cash. Ponzi borrowers are forced to, because they have no cash; speculative borrowers can no longer refinance the principal even if they are able to cover interest payments. The prices of assets fall, with innocent lenders suffering as well as guilty borrowers.
Not everyone suffers. There are those who have taken their margin on each transaction, such as investment promoters, sharebrokers, investment advisers, real estate agents, All have an incentive to encourage speculative investment, which biases the public view towards risky investments. Other beneficiaries are those who invest and cash up before the Minsky Moment. There is also a more sophisticated group of investors who ‘short’ the market, that is, contract to sell the assets at high prices after the Minsky Moment. (Michael Lewis’s The Big Short described shorting during the Global Financial Crisis.)
New Zealand’s housing market fits Minsky’s model reasonably well.
Nowadays, the housing market is largely funded by borrowing from banks. From the 1980s, after the financial liberalisation which, among other things, ended the trading banks having separate savings banks, the housing market was first in Minsky’s Hedge Phase. The banks’ lending was cautious, with their funds for lending largely coming from deposits and loan repayments. Mortgages were advanced on the basis that borrowers could afford to pay the interest and repay the initial principal over a long period reflecting their working lifetime.
Minsky’s Speculative Phase began in the early 2000s where, following 9/11, the George W Bush administration flooded international markets with dollar liquidity. Our trading banks turned to those international markets for additional funds, which were used to increase the supply of mortgages.
It became easier to purchase a house because there were more funds. But the supply of housing did not increase much. So the price of housing rose. Borrowers still serviced their mortgages but they were now getting a good return from the capital gain from the faster appreciation of housing prices. By 2007, housing prices were about 50% above the trend of the 1990s relative to consumer prices.
There was almost a domestic financial crash. In 2008, trading banks were borrowing about $30 billion a month in offshore markets, partly to increase their advances but mainly to roll over existing borrowing which was short term – three months – much shorter than the mortgage advances they were making to house owners. During the GFC, financial markets almost seized up, when international lenders in crisis themselves became unwilling to roll over their past advances – to everyone, not just to New Zealand banks. Fortunately, international cooperation between the central banks of the world prevented the catastrophe.
New Zealand managed to get through the GFC reasonably lightly, compared to some other countries; its house prices fell a bit.
From 2014 the housing prices began moving up again. It was partly over-confidence but nominal interest rates were low, which meant that house purchasers could service larger mortgages. Again there was not much increase in the housing stock, so the price of housing went up dramatically.
The government tried to restrain the house price rises including by imposing a capital gains tax on houses which were quickly resold and loan-to-value requirements on lenders. Additionally, it ring-fenced rental income so that landlord operating losses could no longer be set against other taxable income (notably wage income) although any capital gains they made remained untaxed. Such measures stabilised prices from 2017 to 2020 but at about 70% above the 1990s trend.
But the quantitative easing of the early 2020s (as a part of the Covid package) flooded cash into the banks, who lent it out for housing. It is common to say that such cash stimulates inflation. It did, but not this time in consumer prices. Housing and collectables prices inflated.
By 2021 house prices were about double what they would have been had the mild increases of the 1990s continued. The inevitable happened, especially when mortgage interest rates began rising following rising international interest rates. The Minsky Moment arrived. By the end of 2021 house prices were falling everywhere. How far they will fall one cannot tell, especially as the stock of housing is ramping up.
*Brian Easton, an independent scholar, is an economist, social statistician, public policy analyst and historian. He was the Listener economic columnist from 1978 to 2014. This is a re-post of an article originally published on pundit.co.nz. It is here with permission.
41 Comments
So I'm guessing that the bank economists knew about Hyman Minsky and his understanding of bubbles? For all the above breakdown, Banks are a crucial component in being able to prevent economic 'fragility'. If they fail in this then they are a significant part of the problem, feeding the masses into causing the problem.
It seems to me that this is a case for better bank regulation?
The banks and the RBNZ actually don't read Minsky, he was marginalised because it's heresy to speak of problems to the neoliberal priesthood of beautiful perfect capitalism.
Which is a major problem because "markets" are just people, and they're only efficient when we think they are not and arbitrage out the bad ideas.
If banks and punters had read "stabilising an unstable economy" (I am not sure if Brian has?) then there would have been no bubble and we wouldn't be in an inflationary price spiral (which Minsky also warned was a consequence of government banking bailouts creating moral hazard).
I don't understand this - it seems contradictory? "they're only efficient when we think they are not and arbitrage out the bad ideas."
I haven't read the book either but just guessing, I would say it is taking lessons from history that point to Governments and banks being able to regulate markets to maintain stability? Humans are notorious for ignoring the lessons of history and believing that they don't apply to them, and therefore cannot be repeated. Go figure - DOH!
House prices are tumbling all over the world: https://www.theguardian.com/money/2023/feb/25/house-prices-falls-uk-us-…
Turns out that house prices are overwhelmingly dictated by the price of debt. Whocudaknowed?
Most of 2021 appeared to me to be developers land banking for their next project , as you could see them bid up to a very tight $ per sq m range. Anyone who had a decent house was using this bidding war as proof of the value of the land their house sat upon.
Sure there was a different dynamic going on for FHBers who where bidding freshly built up etc, but the truely nuts money $4k per sq m for bare land size 8-900sq m was developers.
This took off not once Nat/Lab said you could build 3 per site, but before this based on the unitary plan allowing you to cram on one house per 125sqm approx.
At this time you could borrow at high 2's meaning the 12 months to get resource conscent would only cost you 100k per site in funding costs, often withy the sweetner that you could get back 40k in rent from the old house.
when funding costs are only 10k per future site you full your boots, and they did.....
Be that rise of fall, be that normal or speculative, one has to ask, despite the house price drop, where does the money go when housing market messed up? which is still better investment vehicle?
All market is down comparing a year ago, housing market down, share market down, debt market is a joke, TDs losing 3% on average after inflation.
you could call housing market a ponsi scheme, but is it really? when all markets are down? or is it actually just a sudden revaluation of dollar? (I do blame central banks for this sharp change, it's abusing its power as central bank)
properties is still my first choice when investing, even after taking huge loss, on paper, it is still bearing good rental return, and long term capital gain.
"TDs [are only] losing 3% on average after inflation"
Fixed that for you. This is weird whataboutism. It's OK to lose 11% or much more because someone else is only losing 3%.
When, you property investors write about being too lazy to crunch the numbers (that are larger than most peoples salaries) or sell you houses, what image do you think you are giving off? Do you think you are successfully eliciting sympathy because you are a victim or something?
Well, that's an interesting but simplistic metaphor to justify losing 30% (in the Hutt after inflation).
What happens if they trade their monies for other monies elsewhere and go hunting instead of holding onto the liability in the harbour after an entire winter of storms is forecast? (There is not much to work with in this metaphor and I'm not even sure I even understand it correctly.)
I have not seen any rental yields that stack up against current prices. After tax rent will continue to fall until 1 April 2025 and it may be 20 years before you see an inflation-adjusted capital gain. Riding the tax-free leveraged gains gravy train on the way up was fun. Riding it down again will not be.
Cash is a great investment right now as return of capital is more important the return of capital. And anything unleveraged will outperform property on the way down.
two things came to my mind when reading your comments,
first, just 2 years ago, people were saying cash is trash, now "cash is great"? Cash is only great if buys something, or delivers real returns, cash is still trash if doesn't deliver.
second, rental yields suck these two years, especially when house price dropped so much. to many people, maintaining wealth is more of a priority than to create wealth, and properties is still one of the best to store wealth than other investment items. the land under the house does not change and constant.
Another thing I've been wondering lately is, how come inflation sits 7% but rent is only 4%? is it normal? or does it mean rent is about to jump?
You only need to look at the borrowing practices of many specuvestors to see this has happened in the NZ housing market.
Go back a couple of decades and banks would only lend on principle and interest terms.
Then interest only lending became very widespread, and it was no longer considered necessary to repay principle as the capital gains would increase your equity.
And then finally Interest only loans, but with negative net cash flow (and topping up mortgage payments). This became more common due to the widely held belief prices only go up, rates will stay low, and the capital gains will more than make up for the negative cash flow.
'And then finally Interest only loans, but with negative net cash flow (and topping up mortgage payments). This became more common due to the widely held belief prices only go up, rates will stay low, and the capital gains will more than make up for the negative cash flow.'
Interestingly, the description above almost aligns with the below definition from the article...
'The Ponzi borrower – believes that the appreciation of the value of the asset will be sufficient to refinance the debt because insufficient cash flow from investments; only the appreciating asset value can keep the Ponzi borrower afloat.'
He thought that such financial instability – and the booms and busts which accompanies it – was inevitable in a so-called ‘free’ market economy, unless government steps in to control through regulation, central bank action and other tools.
No, Minsky thought that financial instability was inevitable in a free market economy, in spite of government attempts to control it. The FIH states that actors in an economic system adjust to the prevailing conditons and eventually begin to act in a way that is destabilising. Actors begin to anticipate attempts to stabilise the economy, and act in a way to profit from it. This is why QE is such a failure, because now markets expect it and it has lead to massive bubbles everywhere.
The best comment so far. A free market economy is about a lack of government regulation, thus any attempt by a government to manage financial instability would inevitably be too little, too late with no adequate tools to regulate the economy once the slide began.
I think your comment re 'actors' is on the nail too. With little or no constraints on their behaviour, they will feel empowered to fight or push back. The banks in NZ did that during COVID around 'supporting business's'.
Politicians also look to use the free market to their advantage - to get elected, they buy votes when the market is buoyant, compounding the booms. Ray Dalio explains this well if you want to know more. A Two-Part Look at: 1. Principles for Navigating Big Debt Crises, and 2. How They Apply to What’s Happening Now | LinkedIn
Desperation will arrive soon as thee find no one left to buy the houses they bid up into the Ponzi sky!
Price slashes of 50% look like a lock from the bewildering peaks of recent years.
Will TA and AC be able to walk free, without attracting hoards of rotten fruit throwing specuvestors?
JavaBoy, House prices vs CPI is just one metric. You could also compare house prices to rents, household incomes, or other things. There are other things to consider such as changes in demographics, household composition, unemployment rate, types and location of jobs, tax rates, Government policies, etc. It would be far too simplistic to determine an inflection point based on a single chart.
The NZ bubble got bigger than most other countries so the collapse will also be bigger.... many only started to accept that the bubble was bursting recently and we are 20-25% off peak in AKL already, maybe more in WGTN. Wow its been fast. another 30% from the peak to come. much of the last 30% gains where based on what your site was worth to a developer.... now not so much.
"But the quantitative easing of the early 2020s (as a part of the Covid package) flooded cash into the banks, who lent it out for housing"
It seems that not only does Brian Easton not understand how the governments finances operate but he doesn't understand how banking and QE work either,so what sort of economist does that make him?
Standard and Poor's tells us categorically that QE does not give banks money to lend.
https://www.hks.harvard.edu/sites/default/files/centers/mrcbg/programs/…
We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.
Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.