By Martien Lubberink*
Here is a question. Suppose I would ask you to mark some of my students’ exam scripts. And suppose you know that I already marked them. You would be double-marking my scripts. This to make sure the scripts are marked correctly. It’s the four-eyes principle.
Would you make a solid effort?
I doubt it.
Would I make a solid effort to mark the scripts, knowing that you will spot my errors?
I doubt it.
Universities in the United Kingdom rely on double marking. It is an arcane system that only works well in theory. Marking is a chore, double marking is worse. If I know that someone else spots my errors, I will not lift a finger. Neither will the second marker: He conveniently relies on the efforts of the first marker. The result is poor marking. Unfortunately, UK students will never find out that they are affected by poor marking: they are not allowed to view their scripts after an exam (!)
You get the picture. Instead of improving the quality of marking, the four-eyes system compromises it. This because of typical free-rider problems: shirking and gaming.
Four-eyes and bank supervision
Reserve Bank’s Deputy Governor Geoff Bascand reminded me of the vulnerability of the four-eyes principle. His latest speech (“The effect of daylight: disclosure and market discipline”) highlights the virtues of disclosure. Disclosure as a cornerstone.
Bascand appears to encourage the public to monitor banks. However, early on in the speech he reveals that the Reserve Bank has access to much more information than the public. Our bank supervisor has access to private, proprietary, confidential, more granular, and more detailed information. The Reserve Bank is also well-informed about bank regulation, local and international developments, as well as many subtle facts that the public might not know. The public knows this and may expect the Reserve Bank to act on that information, as if the RBNZ is a ‘first marker.’
To help the public understand banks better, there will be the Bank Financial Strength Dashboard. The Reserve Bank will also launch an awareness campaign to promote the Dashboard as a user-friendly, authoritative and reliable source of information.
This is all fine, but the Dashboard will likely produce abbreviated information, i.e. less than the Reserve Bank knows.
Given the significant information advantage and the aforementioned limits of the four-eyes principle, what can the Reserve Bank reasonably expect from the monitoring public in terms of efforts?
Not a cornerstone
I like the Dashboard initiative very much. I also support disclosure initiatives. However, disclosure cannot be a cornerstone. It is one of the many tools of effective bank supervision. By giving disclosures much prominence, the Reserve Bank runs the risk of relying on a public that is insufficiently equipped, motivated, or incentivised to spot important vulnerabilities.
One way to promote awareness of the state of our banks is publishing stress test results. The RBNZ could take a leaf from the European Banking Authority (EBA) book on stress testing. The EBA discloses all stress test data and associated information, scenarios, methodologies, fancy dashboards, etc. This enables the public to better assess the quality of banks. Also because risks tend to build up in quiet times. The RBNZ dashboard may show splendid results on a going-concern basis, but the public also needs to know how our banks perform under stress.
In Europe, the publication of the stress test results is a big event, with intensive press coverage. Having such an event in New Zealand could lead to increased media attention and stimulate interest in our banks. Once bank stress tests are on par with major sports events, I would be less worried about the vulnerability of the four-eyes principle. (The RBNZ doesn't currently publish individual banks' stress test results, but from time to time publishes an industry wide summary).
---------------------------------------
*Martien Lubberink is an Associate Professor at the School of Accounting and Commercial Law at Victoria University. He previously worked for the central bank of the Netherlands where he contributed to the development of new regulatory capital standards and regulatory capital disclosure standards for banks worldwide including Europe (Basel III and CRD IV respectively).
We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.
Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.