Even in the best of times, policymakers find it difficult to explain complex issues to the public. But when they have the public’s trust, the ordinary citizen will say, “I know broadly what you are trying to do, so you don’t need to explain every last detail to me.” This was the case in many advanced economies before the global financial crisis, when there was a broad consensus on the direction of economic policy. While the United States placed greater emphasis on deregulation, openness, and expanding trade, the European Union was more concerned with market integration. In general, though, the liberal (in the classical British sense) orthodoxy prevailed.
So pervasive was this consensus that one of my younger colleagues at the International Monetary Fund found it hard to get a good job in academia, despite holding a PhD from MIT’s prestigious economics department, probably because her work showed that trade liberalisation had slowed the rate of poverty reduction in rural India. While theoretical papers showing that freer trade could have such adverse effects were acceptable, studies that demonstrated the phenomenon empirically were met with skepticism.
The global financial crisis shattered both the prevailing consensus and the public’s trust. Clearly, the liberal orthodoxy had not worked for everyone in the US. Now-acceptable studies showed that middle-class manufacturing workers exposed to Chinese competition had been hit especially hard. “Obviously,” the accusation went, “the policymaking elites, whose friends and family were in protected service jobs, benefited from cheap imported goods and could not be trusted on trade.” In Europe, the free movement of goods, capital, services, and people within the single market were seen as serving the interests of the EU’s unelected bureaucrats in Brussels more than anyone else.
After the old orthodoxy was found wanting, and after its proponents had lost the public’s trust, the door opened to unorthodox solutions. But while thinking outside the box can produce good outcomes, policy prescriptions also need to be easily understood by the untrusting layperson. Therein lie the roots of bad populist policies.
If we need to create jobs, why not erect tariffs to protect workers? If we need to spend, why not just print money (as Modern Monetary Theory dictates)? If we want to revive manufacturing, why not emphasise the danger of depending on China, and offer subsidies and other incentives for firms to reshore or friend-shore operations? If we need to make the financial system safer, why not raise capital requirements on banks still further?
Because the liberal orthodoxy has been discredited in the eyes of the public, many such policies that were anathema to it have now re-emerged. But, equally important, the appeal of populist policies, however unsound or unsuccessful in the past, is that they seem obviously true and are easy to communicate. As the American essayist H.L. Menken famously quipped, “for every complex problem, there is an answer that is clear, simple, and wrong.” After all, who cannot see that import tariffs will protect at least some domestic jobs? Though the jobs saved by new steel tariffs will raise the cost of manufacturing cars domestically, leading to potential job losses in that industry, this point requires an additional step of reasoning that is harder to communicate.
Similarly, replacing a supplier from China with one in a friendly country would seem to make a supply chain more resilient to a potential China-US conflict; but it also may create a false sense of security, considering that many friendly suppliers still rely on China for key inputs. Analogously, raising capital requirements may have made banks safer after the global financial crisis; but to continue raising them will only increase banks’ costs of funding and reduce their activities, leading to a migration of risk into the unregulated, opaque shadow financial sector.
According to the twentieth-century liberal French journalist Frédéric Bastiat, “There is only one difference between a bad economist and a good one: the bad economist confines himself to the visible effect; the good economist takes into account both the effect that can be seen and those effects that must be foreseen.” But when there is no trust, warnings by policymakers and economists about unseen second-round effects simply will not be believed. Those urging fiscal restraint, for example, will be tagged with the Dr. Doom epithet and dismissed – at least until real (inflation-adjusted) interest rates increase to the point that servicing the bloated public debt requires austerity. Seeing is believing, but it comes too late.
Emerging markets and developing countries have been through such cycles before, which may be why some of them have emerged as proponents of orthodox liberal macroeconomic policies this time around. Yet the temptation to pursue unorthodox populist policies remains strong, especially now that rich industrialised countries have embraced them.
Hence, India, despite its terrible experience with the so-called License Raj, recently started requiring licenses to import computers – in part to support domestic production, and in part to reduce its dependence on Chinese imports. But what about the negative consequences for IT service exports (India’s greatest source of export revenue) and for Indian business more generally? Argentina, an addict to populism, seems to be shifting its affections from the left-wing Peronists to a right-wing libertarian, who promises to cure inflation by, among other actions, adopting the US dollar (again!).
It is hard not to be pessimistic nowadays. In industrial countries, the pendulum has swung from excessive faith in the liberal orthodoxy to faith in populist policies, until their deficiencies become obvious once again. The best we can hope for is that, unlike what seems to be happening in Argentina, it will not then swing too far back toward the other extreme, and that we will have learned some lessons along the way.
Raghuram G. Rajan, former governor of the Reserve Bank of India, is Professor of Finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business and the author, most recently, of The Third Pillar: How Markets and the State Leave the Community Behind (Penguin, 2020). Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2023, published here with permission.
16 Comments
Yes. But the ideas under that stem from MMT such as 'govts with their own sovereign currency are not financially constrained' should lead to policy that encourages money printing. MMT thinking is perfect for NZ and leaders like in our current govt, yet they always communicate that the govt / public sector has to 'live within its means' while expecting the pvte sector to load up on debt and behave like drunken sailors - particularly with houses where the private banks operate with full grace to expand the money supply within boundaries that do not protect the integrity of the currency.
People like Marc Faber suggests that ideas like MMT are dangerous because of their post-Keynesian economic framework. I'm not smart enough to take a side, but my intuitive feeling is that Marc is somewhat right.
The real problem is issuing money as debt. Central banks generating money from thin air using the bond process is the evil at its root. The appropriate answer is simply to issue a currency as a unit of work, pay for government programs with it and create inherent demand by allowing it to be used to pay taxes at a discount rate to existing money.
It should along with budgeting and investing to self sufficiency at age 65 or earlier. When I look back, 95% of what you learned at school was useless in real life, all it did was to push you mentally and develop your thinking and "Stream" everyone so they were able to attend University or not, which is not a bad thing, but most stuff you really needed to know to live day to day you just picked up on the fly.
Good teachers make you think and that is what school and the basics learned do for real life. Understanding history is a great teacher if you understand it and apply it to your life. So much of what you learned in school is not useless, but you need to apply it to your life.
Contemporary establishment economists trying to defend their profession by crying about muh steel prices vs jobs lost because of lower demand. What about the absolute record profits of almost all corporate sectors since COVID? It is pissing at the moon.
The obvious historic fact that China industrialised with Cheap Labour, Cheap Commodities and a centrally planned capitalism is never talked about. Japan and Korea did the same, as did Taiwan. They all learned from what Germany had done in the 19th century, with that lesson learned from the United States and Britain respectively on the use of tariffs to protect nascent industries. They all exploited the free trade arrangements and freedom of the seas to grow to what they are now.
The 'economy' does better from globalisation, but almost no one except the international elements of finance capital has benefited. I don't give a toss about the global equity of reducing global poverty, of the percentile of gdp growth etc. Every rural town I visit in NZ is a post-industrial hellhole of downtrodden service economics based around indirect government subsidy, nursing the elderly and 'educating' foreign students, with little else to sustain the economy. These constantly promoted policies have obviously not worked. A mere fob off to the ideas of protectionism and localism from some globalist central bank governor is just insulting, not enlightening.
Most of this stuff is beyond the average teacher. But you're right, the theory is the better we understand it, the better at this game we 'should' get. I'm old but still learning. Everyone should be still learning.
PS: One thing I have learned is that generational wealth is the way to go. But to have generations you need to have families. And [to our cost] if there's one thing we've killed in the last half century it is the family.
What I came to realise was that, in reality, Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) and Quantitative Easing (QE) have been used as little more than seigniorage for asset holders dressed up in a dicky bow. Governments used the low rates environment to defer imposing taxes on assets and wealth, then when rates rose again they taxes workers more.
Helicopter money actually had a much better economic foundation and has real world impact when done during the pandemic. Writing workers a small cheque ended up having a far larger positive impact on consumers than a decade and a half of pumping up asset prices by buying bonds and slashing interest rates.
We fundamentally did the wrong thing after the financial crisis. Why would we ever consider doing that again?
When the layman starts to understand that it is irrelevant what the global economy is doing and more pertinent how individuals manage and expend their capital then economic change might occur. Rampant consumerism abounds and much of it ends up very quickly at the local rubbish dump or impacting the health sector. Product longevity is short as are the fads / voters memories . Those with the power will always throw it down on the masses perceiving themselves as shepherds of mankind and the proletarian lately seems to have devolved into some sloth like creature afraid to speak up or push for a more favorable outcome. We can espouse the grandeur of sound economic policy but sadly its social effect leans heavy to the upper bourgeois by design. Best a privateer economist can hope for is consistent capital growth via self determination . When I think about market regulation it is hard not to imagine a shifting playing field that favors elites . NZ imo is fraught with bad management, so much so I feel its normalised and resulted in a crisis environment whereby everyone waits for the next destined or invented crisis to appear. Until those higher up the Totem pole get it together it will be much the same for NZers . Until folk really understand the value of a dollar it will be follow the FED....lol
"Money's too tight to mention"...Simply Red
The highest value companies make more money in dicking with their stocks than they do from products. The value of average persons savings and equities is evaporated through a few functions of poorly conceived government and bank policies.
To the average person who doesnt know economics and works outrageous hours just to keep the lights on, it's easy to see something is wrong. It's less obvious what the appropriate fix is other than - not more of the same.
The metaphor for this feeling being that we are all leaves on a river rapid. When any amount of work and savings can be whisked away to fix some failure of quantative easing, a nihilistic disconnect from future planning creeps in. Reluctance to spending outside of personal means becomes more a matter of why not - it might all evaporate tomorrow. Similarly any apparently positive hand-me-down policy is latched on to.
None of this is particularly surprising once its realised just how far average people are from having any control of their own outcomes.
We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.
Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.