By Terry Baucher*
For the last 30 years the tax policy of governments of both hues has ostensibly been driven by the broad-base, low-rate (BBLR) paradigm. A broader tax base enables lower tax-rates.
However, as both David Chaston and Alex Tarrant pointed out last week, the effective exclusion of residential property from tax undermines the BBLR. This isn’t a new revelation either, the Tax Working Group’s final report in January 2010 concluded:
“There is a major hole in the tax base for the taxation of capital, which is manifest, for example, in high investment and low taxable returns in the property market.”
The TWG went on to note;
“New Zealand taxes personal capital income, such as interest received on bank deposits, higher than most other OECD countries, and so taxes savings more heavily.”
The tax debate during this year’s election therefore should address the over-taxation of savings, particularly for the over 2.6 million KiwiSaver investors, as well as how the tax system copes with change such as Bitcoin.
The implications of tax on investment returns was also identified by the Savings Working Group in its wide-ranging report on New Zealand’s savings policy in January 2011. With regard to the taxation of retirement savings, the report concluded:
“New Zealand tends to be more reliant (than most comparable countries) on income taxes than on other taxes, and does not have [Exempt Exempt Tax] or [Tax Exempt Exempt] applying to any retirement savings. It is likely, therefore, that the structure of New Zealand’s tax system is more biased against saving than in comparable countries. Further, with no capital gains tax, the New Zealand tax system is biased towards a large block of economic activity – property investment – that tends to be at the less productive end of the spectrum.”
How big is this bias? Some idea can be gauged by the net tax paid by residential property investors relative to that paid by KiwiSaver investors. According to Inland Revenue the net tax paid by residential property investors after taking into consideration the tax effect of losses for the year ended 31 March 2015 was $177 million.
Based on information supplied to the Financial Markets Authority, KiwiSaver funds paid over $222 million in tax for the year ended 31 March 2015, or $45 million more tax than residential property investors.
There aren’t any clear statistics about the value of residential rental property, but in 2009 Inland Revenue provided an estimate of $200 billion to the Tax Working Group. By contrast the value of KiwiSaver funds as at 31 March 2015 was calculated at just under $28.5 billion. Therefore, not only did KiwiSaver funds pay more tax in absolute terms than residential property investors, but once the relative size of the asset bases are taken into consideration, KiwiSaver investors are paying maybe nine times as much tax. The main reason for this huge discrepancy is that the unrealised capital gains of KiwiSaver funds are taxed because of the application of the financial arrangements and foreign investment fund regimes.
An adverse tax treatment relative to housing has significant implications for this group of savers. As the 2011 Savings Working Group report noted:
“The most important tax from the saver's point of view is tax on investment income…. This has a far greater effect on retirement income than a tax on contributions or a tax on retirement income…90% of retirement income is generated by (compounding) investment income.”
KiwiSaver is now 10 years old with over 2.6 million KiwiSaver members. KiwiSaver funds will come to represent the only major asset for the growing number of people locked out of an unaffordable housing market. Politically, a storm is brewing between those relying on KiwiSaver to build up a retirement nest egg but paying significant amounts of tax as they do so, and property owners enjoying substantial tax-free gains. Proponents of compulsory KiwiSaver membership will need to address this issue to avoid severe political fallout in the future.
The Ripple...and Bitcoin...and Ethereum effect
If the current tax treatment of savings means KiwiSaver investors are getting a raw deal, the arrival of Bitcoin and other cryptocurrencies such as Ethereum and Ripple illustrate how the present tax system has its struggles adapting to a fast-changing economy.
There are now some 900 cryptocurrencies in existence and the current market valuation of the top 100 cryptocurrencies is over US$156 billion. Bitcoin investors have seen some huge price appreciations in a very short space of time: the price of a single Bitcoin has gone from US$120 in August 2013 to US$4,348 as of last week. Ethereum investors have experienced even more dramatic growth: from US$2.83 (yes, two dollars eighty-three cents) in August 2015 to US$333.89 last week – a 118-fold increase.
Whether these dramatic gains will continue remains to be seen but cryptocurrencies are going to play an increasing role in the world economy in the years ahead. And their impact is not necessarily just financial. Currently, the worldwide electricity consumption spent on mining Bitcoin is about 16 terrawatt-hours (16,000 gigawatt-hours) or the equivalent to 40% of New Zealand’s TOTAL annual electricity consumption. Demands on power worldwide are therefore likely to increase as the number of cryptocurrency miners increases.
But what is the tax treatment of cryptocurrencies? Here’s where the weakness of the present ad-hoc approach to asset taxation is revealed. Are they within the financial arrangements regime? If so, then as the financial arrangements regime operates on an “accrual” basis, cryptocurrency investors may already have incurred substantial income tax liabilities even if they have not realised any gains. Fortunately, although Inland Revenue has not yet issued any guidance on the matter, my understanding is that it does not consider cryptocurrencies represent financial arrangements.
But if the financial arrangements rules don’t apply and the cryptocurrency holder isn’t clearly a trader, what then? The best answer seems to be that gains will be taxable where either they arise from carrying on a profit-making scheme or undertaking, or from the disposal of property acquired for the purpose of disposal.
Not the answer you want
This elaborate “It depends” is not an answer anyone sweating on a potentially significant tax liability wants to hear but is pretty much the current state of play. It reflects the unwillingness of policy-makers and politicians over the past 30 years to grasp the nettle and either introduce a comprehensive capital gains tax or apply something similar to the foreign investment fund regime’s “fair dividend rate” across all assets.
Other jurisdictions such as Australia, the United Kingdom and the United States have been able to at least provide a measure of certainty by treating cryptocurrencies as falling within their respective capital gains tax regime. The United States Internal Revenue Service issued its guidance on cryptocurrencies in March 2014 and the Australian Tax Office ruled on the topic in December 2014. A capital gains tax regime has its faults but at least provides some certainty to the fundamental issue of whether a transaction is taxable. At present, New Zealand taxpayers are in limbo as we await Inland Revenue’s official guidance on the matter.
The disparities between the tax treatment of residential investment property and that of KiwiSaver investors together with the lack of guidance about the status of cryptocurrencies, are symptomatic of the current confused approach to the taxation of capital gains. This undermines the claims that New Zealand has a coherent BBLR tax policy.
The current ad-hoc approach is in my view unsustainable. Sooner or later, a government will have to take some potentially unpopular decisions and establish a consistent yet flexible approach to the taxation of capital. Properly designed and implemented, there’s no reason why such a move could not result in lower tax rates overall. But which party will have the courage to take that step? More to the point - will voters reward any party proposing such change? Only time will tell.
----------------------------------
*Terry Baucher is an Auckland-based tax specialist and head of Baucher Consulting. You can contact him here »
22 Comments
Tax paid as a proportion of capital:
- Property - 0.09%
- Kiwisaver - 0.78% (note: mix of cash-like and equity investments, FIF and non-FIF, multiple tax rates)
- 17.5% taxpayer with term deposit earning 4% - 0.7%
- 17.5% taxpayer with foreign shares PIE income - 0.88%
- 33% taxpayer with term deposit earning 4% - 1.32%
- 33% taxpayer with foreign shares PIE income (taxed at 28%) - 1.4%
- 33% taxpayer with foreign shares direct holding - 1.65%
So a 33% taxpayer buying say Apple shares will pay about 19 times more tax than a property investor.
You need a lot of assumptions which vary the results significantly but I'll give it a go for you/. If NZ then tax credits are available to NZ domiciled investors as income tax has already been paid by the company. If AU, grey-listed based on income only otherwise FIF as above. Note NZ and AU grey list also could be subject to capital gains (not included below)
With an assumption of 4% yield, 90% imputed:
- NZ shares at 33% - 0.312%
- AU Grey-list at 33% - 1.32%
- AU FIF at 33% - 1.65%
Not defensive at all.
The point is that you purport to provide a "comparison" - but in fact just cherry pick the most convenient examples .
FIF and FA regime are of course pretty terrible - and account for most of the tax paid by Kiwisavers. This however does not mean that property somehow enjoys tax advantages - rather domestic investment enjoys ( arguably unfair ) advantage over overseas investment , across most asset classes
Historically, it's taken crises of various stripes to provide the policy change window. As Rahm Emanuel had it - https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=1yeA_kHHLow - 'you never want a serious crisis to go to waste'.
I guess we'll have to await the next one, wherever That comes from - six or nine years of tax-and-spend under Labour, perhaps? - to supply the incentive for the sorts of tax re-think this article is suggesting.
Labour is just changing the rhythm as they go - not only new taxes will be wasted but future generations will be tied down with more borrowing they criticised National for doing so :
http://www.sharechat.co.nz/article/c098e9a5/labour-eyes-smaller-operati…
Apart from the sheer inequity of effectively subsidizing landlords to compete against first home buyers, and the unfairness of the taxation system, my main issue with the outrageous system is economic.
In Oz, where there is a reasonably balanced tax system, people aren't disincentivised from investing in the share market; hence it is about 20 times the size of the NZ market - with only five times the population. In NZ, investors get a tax credit and then freedom from CGT for investing in housing, which adds zero productivity to the economy, and zero export earnings. It's total economic suicide, and I only ever vote for political Parties that have policy to re-balance the tax settings rationally.
Confusion all round. We also stuff up capital allocation decisions by encouraging borrowing over equity funding due to having a significant inflation tax, officially set at 2%, but subject to random variation between 0% and 20%. Okay, inflation may not officially be a tax, but it functions as such; the first spender, government, gets full value for its' new dollar when it is spent into existence; and the hapless bond purchaser gets repaid in currency units that buy significantly less.
A simpler system with less smoke and mirrors and less room for arbitrary decisions by IRD officials would seem preferable. We weaken respect for our institutions at our peril.
So with btc what's the taxation calculation on an extreme capital gain that is then lost to hackers.
Is the gain deductible when lost/stolen?
Is it from when the event took place or when it was discovered lost or based on the price they would be at year end? Which years end?
President of Property
We welcome your comments below. If you are not already registered, please register to comment.
Remember we welcome robust, respectful and insightful debate. We don't welcome abusive or defamatory comments and will de-register those repeatedly making such comments. Our current comment policy is here.